Despite the
unprecedented attention that income and wealth inequality has received in this
year’s presidential campaign in the United States and in several recent
elections in Europe, one cannot but have the impression that for many centrist politicians,
inequality is just a passing fad. Their belief is, I think, that once the economies
return to sturdy growth of at least 2 to 3 percent per year, and unemployment falls
to 5 percent (or in Europe to single digits), people will just forget all about
inequality and everything will go back
to where it was some twenty years ago. Nobody would care about inequality again.
This, I
think, is an illusion because it disregards the structural changes in societies
wrought by the long and sustained process of increase in wealth and income
inequality during the past 40 years. When there are deep structural changes, reminiscent
of similar processes that have played
out in Latin America during most of the 20th century,
aggregate indicators, such as the growth rate of the economy (which is nothing
else but the growth rate of income at the mean of income distribution, that is around
the 65th or 70th percentile) lose the meaning that they normally
have in economically more homogeneous societies.
I see three such
structural changes: disarticulation of many Western societies, political
influence of big money (plutocracy), and inequality of opportunity.
Disarticulation
was a term used by the dependencia literature
of the 1960s-1970s to express both the divergence of interest and different
positions in the international division of labor of various classes in the developing
world. On the one hand, there was a domestic elite linked with capitalists
internationally, participating in the global economy, both on the production
side (as high-skilled workers or capitalists) or in consumption (as consumers of international goods and services).
And then there was a majority of the population that lacked any connection with
global economy and produced and consumed locally.
The situation in rich countries, and especially
in the United States, is nowadays
somewhat similar (see my earlier post, “Disarticulation
goes North”). There is an elite (whether it is the notorious top 1% of 5%
or even 15%), that is entirely plugged into the global economy and that lives and
consumes globally. Then, there is a shrinking middle class, whose incomes have
been stagnant for 30 to 40 years and which is linked to the global economy in a negative
way, that is, lives in a permanent fear of job or income loss because of competition
from poorer countries or migrants. These groups, rather than the bottom of the
income distribution, are the disenchanted groups, so easily won over by Trump’s protectionist
speeches. I am not discussing whether
their expectations can ever be satisfied in a globalized economy or not; I simply want
to note a deep disconnect between the interests of the top and the interests of
this middle class, a breach that has been created by globalization and rising income
inequality. When the economic interests of the two groups are so divergent, it becomes
hard even to speak of something that would be a “national economic interest”;
moreover the divergence of interests carries over to a number of other
divergences, in the way of life, perception of politics, cultural interests. This
is the first structural gap.
The second
is simply the extension of the first into politics. Due to a number of accommodating
processes, including most famously Citizens United vs. Federal Electoral
Commission, the role of big money in politics, always important in the United
States, has further increased. But even without the facilitating court
decisions (and these decisions could, in turn, be considered endogenous
to the process of income differentiation), the very increase of income inequality
would have brought greater political power to the rich. More concentration in economic
power simply means that there are fewer people who have sufficient funds to help
politicians and political causes they either like or (more probably) benefit
from, and the economic concentration thus naturally leads to the concentration of
political funding. Ultimately, influence in politics simply reflects uneven economic power. This then in turn, as has been argued
by several political scientists (Benjamin
Page, Larry Bartels and Jason Seawright; Martin Gilden’s “Affluence and Influence”)
leads to political decisions that economically favor the elite, and ultimately to further deepening of the economic differentiation.
The third
structural change wrought by income inequality is rising inequality in opportunities. As income inequality
gets more entrenched, it does not end simply In current income inequality but
tends to carry over to the next generations. The chances of success of children
from the rich and poor families diverge. In a process similar to what we can observe
in Latin America, the divergence is not simply limited to inherited wealth, but
is transferred to the acquisition of education (where increasing importance of
private education further exacerbates
the trends), and family connections and networks that are often crucial for success.
Now, these structural inequities will not go away, may even be deepened, when the economy goes back to its long-run rate of growth. Higher rate of growth and lower unemployment might have been sufficient before the structural fault lines became strong because growth would have “papered over” these differences. But when the structural cleavages are deep, growth alone (as we have seen in the case of Latin America, again) is not enough. If I can risk a medical analogy, an ordinary cold may be cured by essentially doing nothing other than lying in bed and taking more liquids. Gradually we revert to the status quo ante. But if the cold continues for a while and transforms itself into a more serious illness, which is what a long process of inequality has done to the body-politic, stronger remedies are needed.
I recently
reread some of Simon
Kuznets’ writings from the 1960s. He argued that every income distribution
should be judged by three criteria: adequacy, equity and efficiency. Adequacy
is ensuring even the poorest have an income level consonant with local customs
and economic ability of the society. Equity
is absence of discrimination whether it is a discrimination in current incomes,
as for example in racial or gender wage gaps, or in future possibilities (what
we now call inequality of opportunity).
Finally, efficiency is achievement of high growth rates. When it comes to the interaction
between equity and efficiency, Kuznets sees it going both ways: in some cases,
pushing for equity too hard, as in full egalitarianism, may have detrimental effect
on the growth rate. But in other cases, the very achievement of higher growth
rates requires greater equity, be it because a significant part of the
population is otherwise socially excluded,
not allowed to contribute, or because it leads to the fragmentation of society
and political instability. I believe
that Simon Kuznets would have seen today’s position of the developed Western economies
as being at that second point, and argued that pro-equity policies are not a
waste of resources but rather an investment in, even the prerequisite, for future
growth.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.