In my
previous post that looked at policies to reduce inequality in the 21st
century, I mentioned that I will next discuss the welfare state. Here it is.
It has become a truism to say that
the welfare state is under stress from the effects of globalization and
migration. It will help to understand the origin of this stress if we go back
to the origins of the welfare state.
As Avner Offer has recently reminded
us in his
excellent book (co-authored with Daniel Söderberg), the origin of social democracy
and the welfare state is in the realization (and financial ability to deal with
it) that all people in their lives go through periods where they are not
earning anything, but have to consume: this applies to the young (hence children’s
benefits), to the sick (health care and sick pay), to those who had a misfortune
to get injured at work (worker’s accident insurance), to mothers when they give
birth (parental leave), to people who lose jobs (unemployment benefits), and to
the elderly (pensions). The welfare state
was created to provide these benefits, delivered in the form of insurance, for either
unavoidable or very common conditions. It was built on the assumed
commonality of behavior or, differently put, cultural and often ethnic
homogeneity. It is no accident that the prototypical welfare state born in
Sweden in the 1930s, had many elements of (not used here in a pejorative sense)
national socialism.
In addition to commonality of behavior
and experiences, the welfare state, in order to be sustainable, required mass participation.
Social insurance cannot work over small parts of the workforce because it then
naturally leads to adverse selection, a point well illustrated by the endless
wrangles over US health care. The rich, or those who are unlikely to be
unemployed, or the healthy ones, do not want to subsidize the “others” and opt
out. The system that would rely only on
the “others” is unsustainable because of huge premiums it would require. Thus the welfare state can work only when it covers
all, or almost all, labor force, i.e. when it is (1) massive and (2) includes people
with similar conditions.
Globalization erodes both requirements.
Trade globalization has led to the well-documented decline in the share of the
middle class in most western countries and income polarization. With income polarization
the rich realize that they are better off creating their own private systems because
sharing the systems with those who are substantially poorer implies sizeable income
transfers. This leads to “social separatism” of the rich, reflected in the
growing importance of private health plans, private pensions, and private education.
The bottom line is that a very unequal, or polarized, society cannot maintain an
extensive welfare state.
Economic migration to which most of
the rich societies have been newly exposed in the past fifty years (especially so
in Europe) also undercuts the support for the welfare state. This happens
through inclusion of people with actual or perceived differences in social
norms or lifecycle experiences. It is
the same phenomenon as dubbed by Peter
Lindert lack of “affinity” between the white majority and African Americans
in the US which rendered the US welfare state historically smaller than its European
counterparts. The same process is now taking
place in Europe where large pockets of immigrants have not been assimilated and
where the native population believes that the migrants are getting an unfair share of the benefits. Lack
of affinity need not be construed as some
sinister discrimination. Sometimes it could be indeed that, but more often it
may be grounded in correct thinking that one is unlikely experience the lifecycle
events of the same nature or frequency as the others, and is hence unwilling to
contribute to such an insurance. In the US, the underlying fact that African Americans
are more likely to be unemployed probably led to less generous unemployment
benefits; similarly, the underlying fact that migrants are likely to have more
children than the natives might lead to the curtailment of children’s benefits.
In any case, the difference in expected lifetime experiences undermines the homogeneity
necessary for a sustainable welfare state.
In addition, in the era of globalization
more developed welfare states might experience a perverse effect of attracting less
skilled or less ambitious migrants. Under “everything being the same” conditions,
a decision of a migrant where to emigrate will depend on the expected income in
one country vs. another. In principle, that would favor richer countries. But
we have also to include migrant’s expectation regarding where in the income distribution
of the recipient country she expects to end up. If she expects to be in the low
income deciles, then a more egalitarian country with a larger
welfare state will be more attractive. An opposite calculation will be made
by the migrants who expect to end up in the higher ends of recipient countries’
income distributions. If the former
migrants are either less skilled or less ambitious than the latter (which is
reasonable to assume), then the less skilled will tend to choose countries with
more developed welfare states. Hence the adverse selection.
In very abstract terms, the countries
that would be exposed to the sharpest adverse selection will be those with large
welfare states and low income mobility. Migrants going to such countries cannot
expect, even in the next generation, to have children who would climb up the income
ladder. In a destructive feedback, such countries will attract the least skilled
or the least ambitious migrants and once they create an underclass, the upward
mobility of their children will be limited. The system then works like a self-fulfilling
prophecy: it attracts ever more unskilled migrants who fail to assimilate. The natives
tend to see migrants as generally lacking in skills and ambition (which may be
true because these are the kinds of people their country attracts) and hence as
“different”. At the same time, failure
to be accepted will be seen by the migrants as confirmation of natives’
anti-migrant prejudices, or, even worse, as religious or ethnic discrimination.
There is no easy solution to the vicious
circle faced by developed welfare states in the era of globalization. This is
why I argued in my
previous blog for (1) policies that would lead toward equalization of
endowments so that eventually taxation of current income can be reduced and the
size of the welfare state be brought down, and (2) that the nature of migration
be changed so that it be much more akin to temporary labor without automatic
access to citizenship and the entire gamut of welfare benefits. This last point
in discussed in Chapter 3 of my “Global inequality” as well as here
and here.