Perhaps under the influence of Amartya Sen who has written
extensively about Adam Smith (and including here: an article I like a lot), I
had the impression that the contrast between “The Theory of Moral Sentiments”
(TMS) and “The Wealth of Nations” (WoN) was the one between a “softer”, more philosophical,
version of Smith and a “harsher”, more economistic
one.
But after recently reading TMS (of which earlier I might have
read just a few pages), I think differently. I read TMS with an eye towards
Smith’s treatment of income inequality, the rich and the poor. And my impression
of Smith’s treatment of the rich in TMS is that of a clergyman of his time: slight, and at times even strong, contempt for
the rich and their moral failings, but an equally strong acceptance of the immutable
order of the world. To the rich, this world; for the next, we shall see. To the
poor, the message of meekness and acceptance. Their moral fortitude is never
questioned, while that of the rich is. But there is no attempt to change the position
of the poor here below, nor any attempt to expose the origin of the wealth of
the ethically-challenged rich. It is as
if, after Russian privatization, we would deride the taste and the spending
pattern of the oligarchs, but never question the way they acquired oil fields.
Moreover, in a Smithian fashion that has since become his
trademark, the very moral weakness of the rich, their attempts to show off,
lead them, as if by “an invisible hand” to
equalize economic outcomes of themselves and the poor. In a remarkable passage,
where the “invisible hand” is mentioned for the first out of two times ever, Smith
writes:
They [the
big proprietors] are led by an invisible hand [through their spending] to make nearly
the same distribution of the necessaries of life, which would have been made,
had the earth been divided into equal portions among all its inhabitants, and
thus without intending it, without knowing it, advance the interest of the
society, and afford means to the multiplication of the species. When Providence
divided the earth among a few lordly masters, it neither forgot nor abandoned those who seemed to have been left out in partition. “ (TMS, part IV.I.10).
The story is a bit thick: unequal
ownership of land does not really matter because the rich have to spend their
income one way or another, they have to hire cooks, gardeners, farmers to raise
cattle etc. and are thus as if by “an
invisible hand” led to an outcome that in terms of distribution of consumption looks
similar to what it would have been if the land were divided in equal parcels. Obviously, Smith must have known that
this is a joke: me, ordering waiters around and eating best food, is not the
same as me, being a waiter, producing that food and serving it.
Overall, Smith’s tone towards the rich and the poor in TMS is
both patronizing and fatalistic. The rich may be despised, but the order of the
world must not be disturbed.
But the tone in “The Wealth of Nations” is very different. Here, not only are the rich taken to task for their vanity, conceit, and concern with “trinkets, baubles and trifles”, as they were in “The Theory of Moral Sentiments”, but in a much more hard-hitting way, the origins of their fortunes are exposed and often found in spoliation, monopoly and “conspiracy against the public”, as in the famous passage:
People of the same trade
seldom meet together, even for merriment and diversion, but the conversation
ends in a conspiracy against the public, or in some contrivance to raise
prices. It is impossible indeed to prevent such meetings, by any law
which either could be executed, or would be consistent with liberty and
justice. But though the law cannot hinder people of the same trade from
sometimes assembling together, it ought to do nothing to facilitate such
assemblies; much less to render them necessary. (WoN, Book I, Chapter X)
Just think of Davos, Bilderberg and the Trilateral Commission.
Similarly, the rich civil servants never forget to overpay
themselves,
The emoluments of offices
are not…regulated by the free competition of the market, and do not, therefore always
bear a just proportion to what the nature of the employment requires. They are,
perhaps in most countries, higher than it requires; the persons who have the
administration of government being generally disposed to reward both themselves
and their immediate dependents rather
more than enough. (WoN, Book V, Chapter 2)
Now think of many governments across the world, from
Azerbaijan to Zimbabwe, and international organizations from the World Bank to
World Trade Organization.
And what is government?
Civil government…is in reality
instituted for the defense of the rich against the poor, or of those who have
some property against those who have none at all. (WoN, Book V, Chapter 1)
The last statement, although made in the context of Smith’s discussion
of pastoral societies where the first differences in incomes, according to him, appeared, does clearly
apply to all property-owning societies.
The statement is so similar to Marx and Engels’ one from the “Communist Manifesto”
(government as “a committee for managing the common affairs of the bourgeoisie”)
to be practically undistinguishable.
Why was Smith much tougher on income inequality and the rich in
the “Wealth of Nations” than in the “Theory of Moral Sentiments”? I think that there are two
possibilities. The subject matters of the two books are different. TMS deals
with ethical matters and the rich can be, in that context, rightly criticized only
for their moral turpitude. In the “Wealth of Nations”, we deal with economics,
and the attention is naturally directed towards more mundane matters: how were fortunes
acquired and how are they preserved.
A different possibility is that there was an evolution in
Smith’s own thinking. While earlier he took social stratification as given, perhaps
“God-ordained”, once he started analyzing more carefully where it really came from, he became much more critical.
I am not a Smith specialist, nor do I know Smith biography well enough, to be able to tell which of the two hypotheses is more likely. But I do think that there is a clear difference in his attitude toward income and wealth inequality and especially the rich in the two books, and the difference is, in my opinion, exactly the reverse from the one that I understood from Sen.