People who have read my
posts in the past two years might have noticed that I discussed several times
the origins of World War I (here
and here
and here).
There are two reasons why I believe this is important. First, very few people
would disagree that our world is still shaped by what happened then. Not only
did the war finish off semi-feudal systems in Europe, and destroyed four empires,
it set the world onto Communist, and later Fascist revolutions, and likewise to
decolonization. So most of what politically exists today has its origin in 1914.
The second reason is that the period which preceded World War I was a period of most complete globalization
up to date, relatively free trade, and (what would be called today) neoliberal
policies. Thus the similarities between that world and our own are many.
The theories of what caused
the war are almost as numerous as the theories of what caused the fall of the western
Roman Empire. Without going into any of them, I think they can be usefully divided
into theories that stress economic factors, those that emphasize politics, and finally
those that believe in accidents. For me,
and I would say for most economists, it is the former (economic theories) that
we are most interested in, and perhaps because of that, find most sensible. In
my new book “Global
inequality: a new approach for the age of globalization”, I use one of them, the Hobson-Lenin theory that
sees the origin of the war in domestic maldistribution of income, struggle for foreign
markets and the need to physically control the territories where the investments
are made.
Avner Offer’s excellent book “The First World War: An Agrarian Interpretation” (published in 1991) also
provides an economic, but somewhat different, explanation. Offer’s particular
take on the origins of the War may not be as well known, so let me give here a
summary and interpretation.
Offer starts with the repeal
of the Corn Laws in 1846. The repeal of the Corn Laws opened British
agriculture to foreign competition. British agriculture could not compete, so
most of the food had to be supplied from overseas. This required control of the
seas. The fleet became the substitute for tariffs. Britain became richer as it
"allowed" the movement of labor from less productive agriculture to industry,
but its economy and society became more fragile. The navy, as Offer nicely puts
it, took the role of tariff rates. While the Corn Laws existed, the tariffs
made sure that there was enough food for workers; without the Corn Laws, a
strong navy had to make sure the food would be shipped to Britain.
Thus, Offer implies, and
at times argues, specialization and international division of labor directly
led to the need for a strong military. Free trade was underwritten by arms.
But this particular calculation
was not limited to Britain. As other nations started to develop, especially so Germany,
they faced the same trade-off. Either Germany kept a significant share of its population
on land in low productivity agriculture, or it went at full speed into manufacturing
for which it needed labor to move to the cities and the food to come from
elsewhere. So Germany like Britain had to make sure that it could be supplied
with food and raw materials which implied also a buildup of a navy and stronger control over the agricultural
neighbors who produced food, mostly in the East (Russia or what is today the Ukraine),
and in the Balkans. (You can see there, if you wish, the seeds of the food driven Lebensraum doctrine, a point recently made
by Timothy Snyder.)
Another element came into
the picture as well. As both the British and the Germans sought to ensure the safety
of their food supplies, they realized that, in the case of a war, food
supply was a weakest spot for both. It
was especially sensitive because neither country’s ruling class could be sure
of the loyalty of its workers once the war began and food shortages spread. Socialist
parties and workers’ movements, before the war, often implied as much. Either a
socialist revolution or capitulation or both loomed (as indeed they eventually happened
in Russia, Germany and Austria). It thus gradually dawned on both British and
German military planners that the most
effective way to fight the enemy was to disrupt its food supplies and the surest
way to remain invulnerable was to have a navy powerful enough to repel all such
attempts by the other side.
The civilian populations became
the prime war target. (Offer opens the book with the ultimate effect of this
strategy: hunger in Germany in the months before the Armistice and all the way to
the signing of the Versailles peace treaty.) Each military advance in either UK
or Germany gave only a temporary respite until the move was matched by the other
side. From that point onward, it was only
a matter of time and opportunity when the conflict would break out.
I will not go over the very
elaborate details that Offer provides on British strategy to hit Germany at its
(if I can use this dubious pun) “soft belly” (food supplies). It ranged from naval blockade of North German
and Belgian and Dutch ports to land invasion of Northern Germany. The planning took place between 1905 and 1914
but the facts were not revealed until the 1960s because they would have fallen
under the rubric of preparations for an
aggressive war, which the Allies, at Versailles, claimed only Germany did
before the war.
There is here one very
important point to notice for the economists. Unlike those who (somewhat
wrongly) interpreted Ivan Bloch and Norman Angell to have believed that
increasing interaction and economic links between the countries would make the
war unthinkable, Offer implicitly argues the very opposite. It is precisely the
decision to specialize in the production of manufactures (that is, to produce something
for which Britain or Germany possessed comparative advantage) that led to the need
to have a war machine and ultimately to the war itself: "the adjustment to economic specialization was the root cause of the war" (p. 327). World War I was in
effect the first war of globalization.
While international
division of labor makes the costs of wars exorbitant for all participants, it also
requires, in order that the system be maintained, a permanent armed
underpinning. But that permanent armed underpinning by itself renders the war
more likely because it leads more than one power to make the same calculation and come to the same conclusions. If we were
to replace Britain and Germany from Offer’s book by US and China today we would
not be very much remiss.
More diversified, less autarkic, countries become much more productive
but at the cost of being more fragile and brittle to any disruption. Our very
sophisticated economic system can be brought to a complete halt by (say) one
month breakdown of all electronic communications. In 1926, Vladimir Mayakovski, after spending
some time in New York, wrote this:
Exactly under Wall Street runs a metro tunnel. What would happen if it were
filled with dynamite and the entire street were to blow up and disappear into
the thin air? Gone too would be the registers of deposits, titles and serial
numbers of innumerable shares, and the columns of data on foreign debt. (America, Gallo Nero Publishing, Madrid, 2011, p. 120).
Mayakovski was as far
from being an economist as every poet is but sometimes poets can see better into
the future than economists.
Finally, I would
like to mention three excellent chapters
iin Offer’s book on the opposition to Asian migration into Canada, US,
Australia and New Zealand. They bring, very timely, all the themes with which
we are familiar today: the anti-immigrant attitude of the (White) working class
which saw in Asian labor a competitor against which they were bound to lose, the
rise of populist politicians, inconsistent racial stereotyping (Asian were
attacked both because they were “inferior” to European migrants, but also
because they were “superior”, smarter and more hard-working), seizure of would-be
migrants’ assets (called then the “landing fees” that Indian and Chinese workers
had to pay upon entry into Canada and the US), and finally outright ban of
Asian migration. Yet one additional reason not only to read the book but to
reflect on how the pre-1914 period is so scarily similar to our own.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.