When I wrote “The
haves and the have-nots” which is a book of inequality vignettes linked
with three essays (on global inequality, inequality between countries, and
inequality within countries), I stumbled upon the idea of representing
inequalities in different countries and eras by using the data and stories provided
by works of fiction.
The idea arose out of several dinner conversations with my wife
who is a great admirer of Jane Austen. I barely knew Jane Austen’s name until
20 years ago. But at my wife’s insistence I started reading her and was thoroughly
impressed by her wit, use of irony, and sharp and critical eye for social status
and conventions. I read “Pride and Prejudice” first, followed by “Emma” and
then “Mansfield Park” (have not read the other two).
Then, one evening as my wife and I were discussing Elizabeth and
Mr. Darcy, I was struck when my wife reeled off the amounts in pounds that
Darcy received annually compared to Elizabeth’s parents. Continuing the
conversation, I hit upon the idea to include the data from “Pride and Prejudice”
in a vignette. This was helped by the fact that a few
years earlier I wrote with Peter Lindert and Jeffrey Williamson a paper that
used English social tables, including Patrick Colquhoun social table from
1801-3. The table almost exactly coincided with the years when the plot in “Pride
and Prejudice” is supposed to happen. I was thus able to very nicely locate
Darcy, Elizabeth (in her unmarried status) and Elizabeth if she decides not to
marry Darcy but to depend on the inheritance of less than 50 pounds per year—a prospect
menacingly dangled by the tactless Reverend Collins as he proposes to her—in the English income distribution at the time.
As the table below shows, the range of options for Elizabeth goes
from being in the top 0.1% of England’s
income distribution to being at the median. The income gap between these two
options is 100 to 1. (When she marries Darcy, their household per capita income becomes 5,000 pounds; hence: 5,000/50=100.) As I wrote, “the incentive to fall in love with Mr. Darcy seems
irresistible”. The last column shows how
much has the gap shrunk today compared to what it was two hundred years ago:
being at the equivalent positions in 2004 (which were the most recent data that
I had around 2009 when I was writing the book) yields an advantage of 17 to 1
only.
I decided also to include the story of Anna Karenina in the
second vignette of “The haves and the have nots”. Her social trajectory is
fairly similar to Elizabeth’s. We learn from just one Tolstoy’s sentence that her
family was around the middling income status. With her marriage to Alexei
Aleksandrovich Karenin, with whom she lives in a palatial home, she moved up to
the top 1%. But with Count Vronsky, not unlike Elizabeth with Darcy, Anna moves to the
rarefied circle of the extremely wealthy, belonging to the top 0.1% of Russia’s
income distribution around 1875. Her lifetime gain was 150 to 1, that is, even
more impressive than Elizabeth’s.
I then considered adding Balzac’s “Le Pere Goriot” which I liked
a lot and which was much admired by Marx (see “Karl
Marx and World Literature” by S. S, Prawer) precisely for his impitoyable depiction of financial capitalism in France. I
collected lots of data, but then decided that adding a third very similar vignette
may be a bit of an overkill. So I left
it out. (A few years later, Thomas Piketty employed a similar technique in his “Capital
in the 21st century” and drew heavily on Balzac.)
Now, Daniel Shaviro in his new and exciting book “Literature
and Inequality: Nine Perspectives from the Napoleonic Era through the First
Gilded Age” has expanded this
approach to three epochs and nine books. In the first part of the book (England and France during the Age of Revolution),
Shaviro discusses with the same objective of retrieving the facets of social
and economic inequality, but in much greater detail than I, Jane Austen (“Pride
and Prejudice”), Balzac (“Le pere Goriot” and "La maison Nucingen") and Stendhal (“Le rouge et le noir”).
In the second part (England from the 1840s to the start of the First World War) Shaviro looks at Charles Dickens, Anthony Trollope
and E M Forster. Finally, in the third part, he trains his gaze on the US Gilded
age (Mark Twain and Charles Dudley Warner, Edith Wharton and Theodore Dreiser).
I will review Shaviro’s book in my next post. I have to say that unlike the
first part, I am not familiar with the authors from the second and third parts
(with the exception of E M Forster), and I would thus have much less to say about
these books. My regret is that Shaviro did not include Francis Scott
Fitzgerald in the third part. Scott Fitzgerald is, I think, a perfect writer
for the Gilded Age: perhaps even better in “Tender is the Night” than in “The
Great Gatsby”. But either would do.
I would like to finish this post with an observation. After publishing
“The haves and the have-nots” I became somewhat interested in finding similar sociologically
rich but also empirically substantiated (i.e. full of details and amounts of
actual incomes) books in other literatures. I looked around myself and asked
several of my students from different countries for their suggestions. Interestingly,
we came with almost nothing. There are of course books with sociological and anthropological
details, but alas no numbers that would allow empirical economists to weave their
story and place these individuals in contemporaneous income distributions
(assuming, of course, that such distributions for the relevant countries do
exist). The writers seemed much less interested in doing this than for example Balzac
in his entire “La comedie humaine”.
This is not the result of some dedicated search of various literatures
and it could be that I am wrong. But it is an interesting hypothesis: was the European
19th century literature exceptionally interested in social status, wealth
and income? Was it exceptionally well documented? It seemed to me that the 20th
century literature provides many fewer empirical details. For example, Proust’s
“A la recherche…” is very similar in its
study of social conflict and mutual accommodation between the parvenus, bourgeoisie
and the aristocratic elite to Balzac. But unlike Balzac, Proust gives no numbers
at all. So for an empirical economist (and for this specific purpose) Proust is
not of much use. This was my impression with other writers I know, but I hope
that there are out there works of fiction in many literatures that one could
use as I have used “Pride and Prejudice” and Piketty and Shaviro “Le pere Goriot”. One of
the objectives of this post is to stimulate people to look around among the
authors they know and to use works of fiction to tease out and trace the
contours of inequality in various societies.
Correction: Reverend Collins estimates Elizabeth's income, if she does not marry, at 4% of 1000 pounds = 40 pounds rather than 50 as I wrote here.
Correction: Reverend Collins estimates Elizabeth's income, if she does not marry, at 4% of 1000 pounds = 40 pounds rather than 50 as I wrote here.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.