[This is the transcript of a talk I give at the conference on inequality organized by the Fondazione Centesimus Annus at the Vatican in May 2014.]
Thank you very much, Professor Curzio. I will stand up so that you would be able to see the PowerPoint. I would like to thank you for the invitation. I am obviously delighted to be here, and I would also like to thank my commentators, Professor Lui and Professor Pastor, who will speak afterwards.
Thank you very much, Professor Curzio. I will stand up so that you would be able to see the PowerPoint. I would like to thank you for the invitation. I am obviously delighted to be here, and I would also like to thank my commentators, Professor Lui and Professor Pastor, who will speak afterwards.
I would also
like to ask the Chair to let me know when I am three minutes off my beeping
time, because I would like to wrap up with something which is relevant, I
believe, for the session and the conference that we are attending today.
And now let
me go over a review of the facts that many of you do know, but which, I think, are
useful to see perhaps once more. First,
over the last twenty five years, in most countries in the world, there has
been an increase in inequality.
In Figure 1 here
I am showing the changes in the Gini coefficient, which is a measure of inequality, such that when it goes up it
means that there is greater inequality. In two-thirds of the countries, most
notably in the United States, the United Kingdom, China and Russia, there was a
large increase in inequality.
Figure 1. Ginis
in the late 1980s and around now
The exception
- and I will not have time to speak about that today - is Latin America, in
particular Brazil; which is very unusual because these countries are countries
with a very high level of inequality. That high level is finally going somewhat
down, whereas in many countries as, for
example in Sweden which is a country with a low level of inequality, inequality
has gone up. There is thus a certain amount of convergence in within-countries’
inequalities.
That is maybe
better shown if you look at this comparison in Figure 2 between the late 1980s
and today. Countries are represented by
the dots. All the dots that are above
the 45-degree line are the cases where you had an increase in inequality. And when
we make the dot size reflect the population size of the country, then it is even
more striking because really big countries like China and India and the United
States, and Nigeria and Russia, all registered an increase in inequality.
Figure 2. Ginis
in the late 1980s and around now
This, of
course, raises many issues which are well known, so some of them, in order to
save on time, I will just read off from the slides.
I would like
to mention one issue, namely interaction between perception of inequality and actual measurement of inequality. It seems to
me that at some point when a society starts seriously to discuss the topic of inequality and when measurements of
inequality are done and published, people suddenly realize that there is really
more of it than they thought. I think a good example of that is the Arab
Revolutions, where we really could not find in measurable terms, increases of inequality
in Egypt or Tunisia, but where the perception of inequity and inequality had
certainly gone up in the past 20 years.
Another
issue is social separatism of the rich.
I will not explain it as I think the term itself is very clear. And then of
course another issue is tax evasion and hidden wealth of the rich, whose
magnitudes we are only really trying to
guess now.
Now, in a
sort of contradictory movement, we have had at the same time the fact that between country inequality, although
very high by historical standards, has been on the decline. And the reason for
this is very high growth rate of China in particular, but also of India, Indonesia, Vietnam.
Essentially
China was the force that was driving the decline in between-country inequality
and thus in global inequality for the past 30 years. However, inequalities between countries are
still huge. Just how huge they are I hope to show in one although a bit complex
graph. The graph (Figure 3) shows the following: on the horizontal axis, you
take everybody in a given country divided into 100 groups (called
“percentiles”) from the poorest group, number 1, to the richest, which is group
100.
And then you
ask, “Okay, this is really the poorest people in such and such country. How do
they stack up within the global income
distribution? Where are they?” Now, this is shown on the vertical axis: you put
there everybody in the world, in similar one hundred groups, from the poorest
to the richest.
I will show the
situation for only a few countries, but obviously this can be done for all
countries that I have in my sample, that is more than 120. Take the United
States, which is a rich country. And then start with the poorest people in the
United States who are on the far left on the horizontal axis. They are very
poor in the United States, but when you put them in the global income
distribution, they come to something like 54th percentile. So they
are richer than one half of the world! And then of course, as you go on with the
next poorest group in the US and further on, they of course are all richer and richer, higher placed
globally, and finally the 12% of the richest Americans are all part of the
global top 1%.
Figure 3. Different
countries and income classes
in global income distribution in 2008
in global income distribution in 2008
This is not
very different for countries like Italy or Germany or France. I think in Italy
too there would be something like 3% of the richest Italians who will be part of
the global top 1 percent. But compare that –and I could have taken many
other countries here, for example from Africa—with a poor country like India and then you get a
very striking figure. We knew of course that people who are poorest in India
are also among the poorest in the world, but we may not have been aware that the
richest 1% of people in India (it is 12 million people though) are really, in
terms of their average per capita income, coming just at the level of what may
be called the lower middle class in the rich, advanced countries. This illustrates
the immense income gaps that still exist between the nations.
Even what is
considered the middle classes in those
poorer countries are by Western terms relatively poor. It is important to keep
this in mind.
I have several
other countries in the Figure here. I will skip them for the sake of time. Of
course, the interesting case is that of Brazil because Brazil combines the
poorest people in the world at the very bottom, and the richest people, those
who belong to the global top 1%. And just to clarify, I am not really talking
here about billionaires and oligarchs, because oligarchs don’t participate in household
surveys. So we are talking here about large groups of very well-off people,
fairly comfortable and living well.
So what
happened to the global inequality?
It is the product of these two things that I have just shown, of within-country
and between-country inequalities. As a short cut in order to have an intuitive feeling about how global
inequality changed, I think it is useful to focus on the three elements or
forces that determine what happens to
the global inequality.
First, I
would like to emphasize the enormous role
played by China. Until about the year 2000 China alone was the force that
reduced global inequality. The other two forces that explain movements in global
inequality are within-country inequalities, which as we have seen, mostly increased
in the past 25 years, and convergence or divergence of mean country incomes.
Here many poor countries, in particular those in Africa, have not been catching
up with the rich world until 2000. After that date, the situation changed and
we currently experience convergence of mean country incomes: poor countries’
growth rates tend to be higher than the
growth rates of the rich countries.
So how does
it look on the global level, when we look at global inequality only? This is
shown by the green dots (Figure 4). Please have a look at them now. The
horizontal axis is time: the vertical axis is a measure of inequality. We focus
on the green dots. They give us the estimates of global inequality among
all people in the world where calculations
are done as if they were all part of one country.
Figure 4. Three
concepts of international inequality, 1952-2013
We adjust for the differences in price levels because
in poorer countries the price level is lower; poor countries’ incomes thus get
a boost compared to the situation where we would just convert their local
currency incomes into dollars at the current exchange rates. Let me also note
that in these 120 plus household surveys which follow broadly the same,
well-established UN methodology of data collection, we are including between 10
and 11 million of individual observations of incomes.
The level of
global inequality is very high: Gini is 70, which is much higher than Gini of any
individual country. It is a higher than South Africa’s Gini which is, as you
know, the most unequal major country in the world.
But there is
one more element that you can see there: at the very end of this period, and
now I have some other preliminary results for 2011 which I did not put on this graph as well,
the green dot (Gini) is lower than it was some ten years ago. We hope to see
there the beginning of a decline in the
global level of inequality.
Now I would
like to say this: this is a historical moment. Although for the past we
do not have household survey data, we do have some rough estimates of what was
global inequality around 1820 or 1850 and all the way to 1970-1980 when we
begin to have household surveys from most countries in the world. I will not go
now into how we made these guesses for the past, but they are educated “guesstimates”,
not made by one person.
We know that
there was a steady increase in global inequality from 1820 to around the middle
of the 20th century. The increase was at first driven by the Industrial
revolution; but it was also driven by the simultaneous stagnation of incomes in
China and India and Africa. The gaps continued to widen in the first half of
the 20th century, when many of the future Third World countries were
colonies and did not experience economic growth.
Now, for the
first time since the Industrial revolution we have a slight reduction in global
inequality, perhaps even the beginning of a stronger and steadier decline. I
don’t think that we need to exaggerate the importance of this change. It
is indeed a welcome change and it is extremely hopeful. I think we should be
gratified that it has happened, but we should not only focus on what may be called
the “Delta Economics”, that is looking only at the changes and forgetting about the levels.
Because we should not forget that the level of global inequality is extraordinarily
high by any measure you use.
A slight
technical issue which has a bearing on what I just said about the possible beginning
of a decline of global inequality. In our data we are including most of the
world, but our numbers are still underestimates of the real level of inequality
because many poor countries that are in civil wars or where the data cannot be
gathered (essentially those in Africa)
are not well represented. As you can see in Figure 5, the population coverage
in the data for global inequality, which I
have just discussed, is 78% in Africa in 2008 and 70% in 2011. And you
can be sure that these 22% or 30% of the missing people in Africa are really
mostly very poor people in very poor countries. Thus if we could include them, there
is little doubt that global inequality would go up.
Figure 5. Population
coverage by household surveys
Now, I want just to show one more graph which is I
think is an important one because it shows the change between 1988 and 2008, at different points of the global
income distribution. And then I would like to go into three political or moral issues
which I believe can be derived from I
have said so far.
So here is
the graph (Figure 6). I am sorry that I have too many graphs, but that is the
reality of the world for somebody who
works with numbers. Here, on the horizontal axis, you have again the percentiles
of the global income distribution, from the poorest on the left of the axis to
the richest on the right. On the vertical axis
I show the real increase in income between 1988 and 2008.
Figure 6. Real
income growth at various percentiles of global income distribution, 1988-2008
Now the
interesting part is that at income levels around 3 to 7 international dollars per day,
you have large percentage gains between 1988 and 2008. And that is essentially among
the people whom one can call, broadly,
the Asian or Chinese middle class. These
are fairly poor people by Western standards, but they have had large increases
in their incomes over the past 20 or 25 years.
The
interesting part of the graph are also people who are at a fairly high position
by world standards, around the 80th global percentile, but who have not seen much of the increase in their
incomes. These are the middle classes of the rich
world.
If you look
at the data that we have for Japan, Germany, the United States, there was a
clear stagnation of median incomes in those countries. So the question then
becomes –and I will not go into it today –are these two developments related?
Is the stagnation of the incomes of the middle class in rich countries somehow
related to the emergence of the new
global middle class? This is
obviously a very important question, perhaps one of the most important for
today’s world.
What you can
also see in this graph is, at the very top, large income increases, in
percentage terms and even much more in absolute terms, of the global top one
percent.
This is
essentially what we now see in the global income distribution. First, we have
the emergence of what is called by some the Global Middle Class. I don’t like the
term very much because I believe that by saying ‘middle’ we give a misleading
impression of people who live with relative ease, of what may be Western middle
class income. But these are people who are just above the global poverty line,
people living with incomes of 4, or 6, or 10 international dollars per day. They
are significantly better off than they were 20 years ago, but they also can slip back
into poverty.
So let me go
now into the three issues that I mentioned before. I discussed them in my writings individually but I put them
together for this conference: the issues of justice and politics. The first one
is what I call the “citizenship rent”; the second is the issue of migration,
and the third is the hollowing out of the middle classes in rich countries. Let
me start with what I call the citizenship rent.
Given the
fact that most of income inequality in the world can be explained by income
gaps between countries, and that if I were to take incomes of all the people in
the world I would be able to explain perhaps about one-half of the variability
in these incomes with only one variable—the country where a person lives, you
directly come to the issue of the citizenship
rent.
In other
words, people who live or are born in rich countries, do receive in some sense
an income, a life-long income which is derived from an accidental fact of the
place where they were born. The key
issue is then, should we start talking about global inequality of opportunity?
Of course we talk about inequality of opportunity all the time within
individual countries, because we don’t think that people, who are of different
gender or race or were born in one part of the country rather than another, should be treated differently. But we
forget the issue of global inequality of opportunity. Not all of us, but
sometimes I think most of us do forget. Does quest for equality of opportunity
end at nations’ borders?
Now of
course there are arguments against caring about global equality of opportunity, and again I will not have the time
to talk about that, but Rawls, no less, has taken a position which can be
interpreted largely to be against the concern with global inequality or even global
inequality of opportunity. Why? Because it goes against the right of national
self-determination.
I think we
should be aware that there are there two goods, and like many times in life,
there may be a trade-off. We cannot get both goods, global equality of opportunity and national
self-determination, but we should be at least aware that there is such a
trade-off..
If we were
to care only about inequalities within nations, as Rawls would like us to do,
then a global optimum would be simply a
summum of individual country optima: that is, of countries’ own optimum inequality
levels.
The problem
with that is that it would leave untouched the main cause of today’s global
inequality: gaps between countries’ mean incomes. If you reduce national inequalities
but mean differences between US and Mexico, Spain and Morocco, Italy and Libya
remain as they are now, you will not have reduced by much the global
inequality. That is a key issue.
Let us see it
in terms of numbers (Figure 7). If total current inequalities are equal to 98 Theil
points (this is just another measure of inequality, similar to Gini) and you imagine,
just for the sake of the argument, a totally unrealistic scenario where all
individual countries have reduced within-country inequalities to zero, the global inequality number will go
down to only 68. So you will have
reduced global inequality by one-third. This is not much. To really make a dent
in the reduction of global inequality you have to have poor countries grow
faster than the rich, or poor people from those countries move to the rich world.
Figure 7. Global
inequality in Real World, Rawlsian World, Convergence World…and Shangri-La
World (year 2008)
And that is
my second issue, over which I will go very quickly because of lack of time. We
should see where the issue of migration
comes from. It does not come out of the blue. It is a derivative of large
between country gaps that exist today. As we have seen, a key thing for the reduction
of global inequality is poor countries
catching up, in terms of income levels, with rich countries. But if this is not
feasible, or is not sufficient alone, then
migration comes in. From the
point of view of human development writ large, it is the same whether a poor
individual becomes richer in his or her country, or he/she moves to another
country. Consequently the issue of migration, I think, has to be put on the
table, not only because there is more migration now than before, as we know in
Italy every day, but because it is an issue which is derived logically from our
concern with global inequality.
Finally, I
would put on the table an issue which was already implied in what I said before:
it is the question of political
decision-making. Increasingly, our income and employment are determined by
global forces. At the same time, we have political life organized within nation-states and the stagnation of middle-class incomes in
the rich countries.
The latter would
not be a problem if the world had one political authority. Actually the developments
over the past 20 or 25 years are relatively good because lots of poor people
have become better off and those who lost are a group which is relatively well
off. But the question is, in a political world composed of nation-states, entirely
different. It is the following: these whom globalization failed are within
their own constituencies, their own nation states, important and they may not like a globalization that keeps their incomes stagnant. So there I see
two dangers at the national level: one is populism and the other one is
plutocracy. With the first one you mimic democracy and roll back globalization.
You probably also lower the income growth rate of the poor people in emerging economies.
With the second one (plutocracy), you continue with globalization at the cost
of making national democracies largely meaningless. Well, we have here another
trade-off!
I want to
finish my talk by reiterating what I have basically said before. First, to
reduce global inequality you need fast growth of poor countries, particularly
in Africa but also in poor parts of Asia and in poor parts of Central and South
America. This is absolutely crucial. Second, we have to see how to have greater
migration, preserve good aspects of globalization, and not make national democracies
meaningless. Third, we need to make
those who are not benefiting from globalization in rich countries, those whose
incomes have been stagnant, better off through within-national redistributions.
These are the three key political issues in the future years.
Thank you
very much.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.