The recently released World Bank data on national accounts
(GDP per capita, national consumption, CPIs, exports and imports etc.) give us an
opportunity to update calculations of international inequality. Things are not
always very obvious and I will have to explain some methodological choices too.
Using the classification that I introduced in my “Worlds Apart” (2005), I will
review three types of international and global inequalities.
Let’s start with the simplest one. Take all countries’ GDPs
per capita (all expressed in mutually and over-time comparable 2005 international
dollars –based on 2011 International Comparison Project) and calculate Gini
across them. (Ignore whether they are small or populous countries.) The number
of countries varies as there are more countries in the world today than in 1952
when our series begins, so best would be to look at the red line only after 1980.
After that date the number of countries is about constant, and today’s independent
countries (say, Ukraine, Macedonia, Slovakia, Eritrea) are considered as separate
countries even then, when they were parts of larger wholes. (USSR, Yugoslavia
etc. produced the data for their constituent units like the US produces GDP data
for its states).
What do we see in the red line? Increasing Gini between mid-1980s and 2000, implying a divergence of country mean incomes, and then, after
the turn of the century, a convergence. The main reasons for the convergence
are faster growth rates in Africa, Asia and Latin America than in rich countries
(especially after 2007). (People who studied growth economics can easily recognize
here the story of unconditional convergence or divergence calculated using Gini
rather than a regression.)
So that would be the end of the story if each country had the
same population. But obviously they do not. For world inequality, convergence
of China and Chad, India and Israel, are not equivalent. If Chinese GDP per capita
converges to that of the rich countries, this is obviously going to matter
more. To see how much look at the blue line where we use countries’ GDPs per
capita as before but weigh them now by populations. The striking thing is that
after 1978, precisely when Chinese growth picks up, the blue line starts to go down.
At first slowly and then more and more precipitously. After about 2000, Gini seems to be in a free
fall. When we tease out the data a little bit more, we find that up to 2000, the
entire “job” of inequality reduction was done by China. Without China, the blue
line would have gone up. But after 2000, even if we drop China out, the population-weighted
inequality goes down: it is driven down by the fast growth of India (and also
Indonesia, Vietnam etc.). This is why we now have two big engines of international
income reduction: China and India. However, as China becomes richer it may not
play that role for very long. Today, China’s GDP per capita is almost exactly
equal to the world’s average, but India’s is at less than ½ of world average. So
in the near future, India’s growth rate compared to the world would be of
paramount importance.
This would be the end of the story if within each country all
citizens had the same income (i.e., there were no within-national inequalities).
Note that the blue line implicitly assumes this: that all Chinese have the mean
income of China, all Americans the mean income of the United States etc.
Obviously, this is not true. Moreover we know that income inequality in most countries
has gone up. When we try to look at inequality across all citizens of the world
(global inequality shown by the green dots) we leave the world of national accounts
because that world cannot give us data on individual incomes and move to the
world of household surveys. (From US national accounts, I can learn that the average
value of output produced in the US annually is $53,000. But I have no idea what
is the income of the top 1% or of the bottom decile. For that I need to move
to the world of household surveys.)
It should be obvious that the green dots must lie above the
blue line. It should also be obvious that the more important the within-national
inequality, the greater would be the gap between the green dots and the blue
line. This is indeed what we see: global inequality, calculated using the same international
dollars, starts by being around Gini of 0.7, and then, pulled down by the blue
line, begin its downward slide ending at around Gini of 0.63.
Movements in global inequality today reflect two forces: a
big one of Asia’s convergence that brings mean incomes of China, India, Vietnam,
Indonesia etc. closer to the rich world,
and a smaller, but important, force of within-national widening of inequalities.
If in the future Asian convergence ceases, and within–national inequalities go up,
the green dots will move back towards Gini of 0.7. But if alternatively convergence
continues, expands to Africa, and within-national inequalities cease to grow, the
green dots will keep on going down.
This would be the of the story were it not for another problem.
Our household surveys tend to underestimate top incomes (the proverbial top
1%). And the question can then be asked: perhaps we underestimate the height of
the green dots by not accounting fully for the super-rich. Christoph Lakner andI have tried, the best we could, to adjust for that, assuming country-specific
underestimates, and raising, in a Pareto fashion, incomes of the top 10%. That’s
how we got the high orange dots.
Now the situation is not as splendid as before: global
inequality is down compared to the 1980s, but the decrease is more modest:
around 3.5 Gini points rather than almost 7. Could the adjustment overturn the
entire decrease and produce an increase
in global inequality? It is possible but unlikely—because the strength of Asian
convergence is so big, and affects so many people (almost 3 billion) that even
very strong increase in within-national inequalities cannot fully offset this gain.
But we need more and better data to say that with certainty, and indeed one of
the topics that several people are working on right now is how to combine household
survey data (that are very good for 90-95% of national distributions) with fiscal data that are better for top 1%, and
possibly even top 5%.
So, stay tuned!
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.