Yesterday I enjoyed reading and then retweeted the newest
piece that the grand Robert
Skidelsky has written on the (sad) state of economics today. It is an extraordinary
tough and accusatory piece and while the accusations may be at times slightly overdone,
Skidelsky’s last sentence that “the economists are the idiot savants of our time”
can be I think reasonably thought to apply to many of us (economists). Moreover,
Skidelsky’s position is supported by the views of the profession’s greatest
minds, men who were without fail, men of erudition and multiple talents, often
involved in politics, journalism and quotidian rough-and-tumble.
Dismissing this as having been the product of economics’
infancy where Renaissance spirits could prosper while today’s economics has
advanced so much that specialization is unavoidable is not a sensible defense
of fach-idioten. It is not because economics by its very nature is a social
science that must, in order to be relevant and to contribute to its key
objective, namely to the improvement of people’s ordinary lives, include the knowledge
of, and display familiarity with, all the neighboring disciplines, primarily history,
economic history, philosophy, sociology and psychology. Thus, as I think Keynes
is supposed to have said (or at least this is implied in the introduction to
his essay on Marshall) that “one is bound
to be a poor economist is he/she is only an economist”.
There is one point however where I think Skidelsky’s overstretches
his case. It relates to Schumpeter and Skidelsky’s claim that Schumpeter “also
attacked the view of the economy as a machine. Schumpeter argued that a
capitalist economy develops through unceasing destruction of old relationships.”
While the second sentence is, I think,
accurate especially if we think of Schumpeter’s key contribution to economics
(written when he was a young man) “Theory of Economic Development”, the previous
sentence about Schumpeter being a critic of those who see the economy as a machine
is more controversial. In fact, in his monumental “History of Economic Analysis”
(HEA) no economist gets as much praise as Walras for his general equilibrium. Here is Schumpeter (HEA, Chapter V, $1, p.
827, 1980 edition):
[Walras’] system
of economic equilibrium, uniting, as it does the quality of revolutionary creativeness
with the quality of classic synthesis, is the only work by an economist that will stand comparison with
the achievements of theoretical physics. Compared with it, most of the theoretical
writings of that period—and beyond—however valuable in themselves and however original
subjectively, look like boats beside a liner…it is the outstanding landmark on
the road that economics travelled toward the status of a rigorous exact
science.
And Schumpeter then goes on to criticize Walras for paying as
much attention to his applied economics dealing with social justice as to his
general equilibrium masterpiece.
Now, to the extent that modern economic analysis has grown
out of Walras’ general equilibrium (and I think that it seems a pretty
uncontestable proposition) it is wrong to enlist Schumpeter among those
who would have necessarily disagreed with the direction taken by modern
economics. It is quite possible, of
course, that Schumpeter might still disagree, believing that what was useful as
a theoretical construct, ended up being interpreted
by the epigones as an accurate representation of reality. But this is obviously
something that is just a matter of speculation.
Why do we have this “problem” with Schumpeter? Because in his
own work, Schumpeter shows a duality, or even a contradiction, between his
often unquestionable endorsement of “economics as physics” in HEA where it is hailed
as an unambiguous progress toward economics becoming an exact science, and
scarce use of this approach in Schumpeter's own work. His “Theory of Economic
Development” is indeed in its structure very abstract and arid, somewhat
similar to Ricardo’s “Principles” (of whose
methodology, by the way, Schumpeter was very critical in HEA), but is not mathematical
at all. His “Business Cycles” is heavily empirical but shows scant relationship
to Walras and is generally anti-theoretical. (I have to confess that I tried three
times to read his “Business Cycles” and that I always failed. It seems almost
unbelievable that such a splendid writer and beautiful mind produced a work--which
moreover he originally saw as a competitor to “The General Theory”—of, yes, such
messiness and unreadability.)
The bottom line is, in my opinion, that Schumpeter’s positon
is at least ambiguous. He was at the same time a great admirer of the very
abstract general equilibrium approach, and his own practice of economics paid
no attention to it at all.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.