It seems obvious. Let me start with the definitions that
economists who work on inequality use. It is the sum total of all assets that
you own (cash, house, car, furniture, paintings, money in the bank, value of shares,
bonds etc.) plus what is called “the
surrender value” of life insurance and similar plans minus the amount of your
debts. In other words, this is the amount of money that you would get if you
had to liquidate today all your possessions
and repay all your debts. (The amount can clearly be negative too.) The definition
can get further complicated as some economists insist that we should also add the
capitalized value of future (certain?) streams of income. That leads to the
problems that I explained here—but
be this as it may, in this post I would like to take a more historical view of
wealth.
I did that too in my “The
Haves and the Have-nots” when I discussed who might have been the richest
person in history. If you want to compare people from different epochs you
cannot just simply try to calculate their total wealth. That is
impossible because of what is known as the “index number problem”: there is no
way to compare the bundle of goods and services which are hugely dissimilar. If
I can listen to a million songs and read
the whole night using a very good light, and if I put a high value on that, I
may be thought to be wealthier than any king who lived 1000 years ago. Tocqueville
noticed that too when he wrote that ancient kings lived lives of luxury but not
comfort.
This is why we should
use Adam Smith’s definition of wealth: “[A person] must be rich or poor according to the quantity
of labor which he can command”. This means that the extent of one’s wealth ought to be estimated within a
historical context: how many thousands hours of labor one can command if he
were to use his entire wealth. This metric however is easier to implement in
the past than now. When, say in Roman times, countries were at approximately
the same level of income, taking the richest person in Roman and Chinese
empires, and comparing their wealth with the subsistence income (i.e. the usual
wage at the time) made sense because that “usual wage” was the same in Rome as
in China. But if you take Jeff Bezos or Bill Gates with whose wages should you compare
their wealth? Wages of US labor or some notional global wage rate? If the former,
should not then Carlos Slim’s or Russian oligarchs’ wealth be compared to the
average wage in Mexico and Russia? This
is what I did in “The Haves and the Have-nots” and here are the results. They
are from the year 2010-11, but could be easily updated. One can see that Slim
and Khodorkovsky (the Russian super-oligarch before he was jailed by Putin)
were probably the richest people in history—if their wealth is measured in terms
of their county’s wages. And in the same yardstick, Rockefeller in 1937 was
richer than Gates in 2005.
When we do this kind of calculation, we implicitly
look at billionaires potential domestic power: their ability to hire thousands
of people. But notice that here I have
moved a bit the goalposts. I am really measuring wealth in the space of potential
power. Now, that power does not
always require actual financial wealth. It can come from straight political power.
Stalin, to take one example, could have moved much more labor by his decisions
than either Khodorkovsky or Slim. The same is true for many other dictators in history.
This conflation of the amount of money as such and the power
to order workers around leads people to believe that absolute rulers must have been
extraordinary wealthy. The view is implicitly
based on the values of our own contemporary societies that are fully commercialized, and where having wealth comes close to having
power. With people like Trump, Berlusconi, Thaksin, Bloomberg etc. it becomes
even more “natural” to see wealth and power as just one and the same thing.
Wealth also, it is thought, should include the ability to
leave it to your heirs. After all, many people justify their amassing
extraordinary amounts by their concern for family, or maybe for some philanthropic
causes. But what happens when the actual private wealth is low even if the
ability to control an enormous amount of resources is huge? This was the case,
in an extreme way, with Stalin, but also with most communist leaders. Whoever
among them was a supreme leader within his own country had a huge power to move
resources around. They also used for themselves many resources; not (in the
case of Stalin) in an ostentatious
Czarist way but in order to showcase own
power and the power of the state (as argued very convincingly in Vladimir
Nevezhin’s “Dining with Stalin”, reviewed
here). Resources were also used to pay for incredibly high security costs so that no
one could track the movement of the supreme leader. (The same reason that leads
American presidents to always use two or three helicopters and not one.) This resulted in Stalin having access to approximately
twenty residences in different areas near Moscow and on the Black Sea coast.
(Some of these residences were only for
his own use, others were shared with the rest of the leadership). Very similar
was Mao’s situation. Tito had at least seven residences in different parts of
the country.
But what neither of these dictators had was the ability to
transfer such “wealth” to their offspring. Many of them did not much care about
their nearest family—certainly the cases of Stalin and Tito. Mao cared just a
bit more, but his son inherited little; Chiang Ching (Jiang Qing), his widow, even
less and died in prison. Thus, if we make a simple table (see below) of what
wealth consists of, we note that in these cases it did not fulfill all the functions
that we normally assign to it. The reason why it failed to do so is because we
ascribe to wealth the characteristics of our own commercialized societies. In different societies
even if they are relatively close in age and technological development to ours
(like Stalin’s Soviet Union or Mao’s China) the function of wealth was
different. Power was the true wealth—not the mansions that were used ex officio
and that you could not bequeath to your heirs.
Functions of wealth in different
societies
In despotic societies of the past
|
In “high” communism
|
In today’s commercialized societies
|
|
To command people’s labor
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
To move resources (in a macroeconomic
way)
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Only if combined with political
power
|
To live luxuriously
|
Yes
|
Yes (but not quite)
|
Yes
|
To leave it to your heirs
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
We thus find that comparing wealth over different ages is not
only fraught with difficulties or rather impossible because we cannot assign values
to the things that did not exist in the past and exist now, but because we have
trouble comparing wealth in different societies with structurally different
features. We have to realize that it is okay to compare wealth of the people on
the Forbes list so long as they share similar social environment: the same ability
to protect that wealth, to use it to boss people around, to bequeath it. The
moment when these underlying conditions
diverge comparison ceases to be meaningful.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.