In the Financial
Times a few days ago, Janan Ganesh wrote an excellent piece on Theresa
May’s attempts to make British system more meritocratic, or differently put, to
increase upward mobility. But Ganesh writes, if you are really serious about
upward mobility in an era of low growth,
then the upward mobility that the “bien pensant” upper middle classes like to champion,
implies some downward mobility for the progenies of those same upper middle
classes. But not only are they unwilling to contemplate this but they do everything
to make sure the chances of those from the bottom overtaking the sons and
daughters of the rich remain negligible. I have to quote here Ganesh’s full paragraph:
“The room
[at the top] rarely opens up because those mediocrities [mediocre sons and
daughters of the top class] are too well screened by parents who hire private
tutors, buy cultural enrichment, teach etiquette, set expectations, stand as
personal examples of success, coach interviewing techniques, navigate any
bureaucratic maze put before them, set up home in nice areas, arrange
internships via friends and, just to rub in their supremacy, make direct gifts
of cash and assets. To fail under these conditions is a kind of achievement in
itself”.
If we were not hypocritical and really wanted to support
upward mobility or give equal chances to all there are many political measures
we could enact. By listing them, and I am here adding a few from within the US
context, Ganesh shows how totally politically unfeasible they are: confiscatory
inheritance taxes, smaller class sizes in poorer neighborhood funded from the
taxes from the rich, end of tax-exempt status for the richest universities,
moral suasion that rich universities annually transfer 1% of their wealth to
poorer state schools, criminalization of nepotism etc. None of these proposals
will have the remotest chance of being accepted by those who currently wield political
and economic power. Hence, hypocrisy.
Ganesh’s article prompted me to write about what I thought
for a while was a somewhat facile support
of equal opportunities. (I wrote about it a bit before; here).
It is today treated by some as a panacea
and by others as “motherhood and apple pie”, something that must be believed in,
even unreflectively. It has joined the Pantheon of democracy, transparency, accountability
and similar things we preach, do not observe, and never dare to question.
If upward mobility is about the relative positions in a
society, then upward mobility for some implies downward mobility for the others.
But if those currently at the top have a stronghold on the top places in
society, there will no upward mobility however much we clamor for it. This
positional (or relative) approach to mobility is a fairly accurate description
of reality in societies that are growing slowly. In societies that develop quickly
even if a lot of mobility is about positional advantages (and they are by definition
fixed) it can be compensated by creating enough new social layers, new jobs and
by making people richer. Thus the upwardly mobile have some room to move up which
does not require an equal number of people to move down.
In more stagnant societies, mobility becomes a zero-sum game.
To effect real social mobility in such societies, you need revolutions that,
while equalizing chances or rather improving dramatically the chances of those
on the bottom, do so at the cost of those on the top. In addition, they destroy
many other things including lives, not only of those on the top but also of
those on the bottom. (In that way, somewhat ironically, the near equality in
death does the job of equalizing life chances). The French Revolution, until
Napoleon to some extent reimposed the old state of affairs, was precisely such
an upheaval: it oppressed the upper classes (clergy and nobility) and promoted
the poorer classes. The Russian revolution did the same thing; it introduced an
explicit reverse discrimination against the sons and daughters of former capitalists,
and even of the intellectuals, in the access to education.
There is also an age element to such revolutions which fundamentally
alter societies and lift those from below to the top. The young people benefit.
In a beautiful short novel entitled “The élan of our youth” Alexander Zinoviev,
a Russian logician and later dissident, describes the Stalinist purges from a young
man’s perspective. The purges of all 40- or 50-year old “Trotskyites” and “wreckers”
opened suddenly incredible vistas of upward mobility for those who were 20- or
25-year old. They could hope, at best,
to come to the positions of authority in ten or fifteen years; now, that were suddenly
thrown in charge of hundreds of workers, became chief designers of airplanes, top
engineers of the metro. What was purge and Gulag for some, was upward mobility
for others. Or consider the age of Hitler and his closest associates when they came
to power. Hitler was by far the oldest: at 43 years of age (Goebbels 35; Himmler
32). I would not be surprised that something similar is today afoot in many Middle Eastern
societies where a huge inflow of the
young in search of better positions has been met by the wall of stagnant
economies and immovable top. ISIS provides a solution to that: you cannot
become a head of a corporation, or a deputy minister, but you can lead a battalion
of 100 suicide-warriors.
There are other disconcerting things about upward mobility. The Ottomans promoted it by creating a corps
of Janissaries, children born in Christian families that were abducted at a young age, and then through
military drill molded into a most formidable elite Army corps. Many of them
went to rule at the highest positions, including the vizier or the prime minister.
This is a beautiful example of both upward mobility and ethnic non-discrimination.
But at the origin of that great example
was a crime of abduction of children from their parents.
It is then not surprising that, short of such massive
upheavals that shake the societies to
their very core, countries tend to display relatively little positional
mobility. The two recent studies, of Sweden
and Tuscany,
found this by examining the names of most eminent families over several centuries
and came to the conclusion that they have little changed.
I think that we are led to a very somber conclusion here. In societies
with slow growth, upward mobility is limited by the lack of opportunities and
the solid grip that those who are on the top keep over the chances of their
children to remain on the top. It is either self-delusion or hypocrisy to
believe that societies with such unevenness of chances will come close to resembling
“meritocracies”. But it is also the case that true upward mobility comes with
an enormous price tag of lives lost and wealth destroyed.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.