1. The question
Over the
last century and a half, global inequality has increased from approximately a
Gini of 55 to a Gini of 70. Assuming that (1) incomes in the world are
distributed lognormally, and (2) that individual welfare is a logarithmic
function of income, we ask the following question: is the increase in mean global
income which has occurred over the same period
sufficient to have compensated for the increase in inequality, measured
by the Gini?
2. Welfare, mean income, and
dispersion of a distribution
2a.
Welfare, mean income and standard deviation of logs of income
Incomes (y)
are a (non-transformed) variable that follows a lognormal distribution with the
mean μ and the standard deviation σ,
that is y:Λ(μ,σ).
Consequently,
the transformed variable log y is normally distributed with the mean m and
standard deviation s, that is log y: N(m,s).
Note that m
and s will be small values because they are the logs of a variable like
income. Thus, the mean income μ will be a much larger number than m which is
the mean of logs of income. The same
is true for σ, the standard
deviations of actual incomes, which is a
large number as opposed to s which is a small number-- a standard deviation of logs
of income.
The following two relationships hold:
The mean of
the lognormal distribution, i.e. the mean of actual incomes, is:
(1)
And variance
of actual incomes,
Thus, ln μ = m+(s2/2) and so
(2)
The last is
a standard relationship. It is crucial
for our purposes because m is the mean (expected value) of logs of income.
Thus, if utility is a logarithmic function of income (W=log y), then m will be
the expected value of utility (i.e., mean welfare in a community); ln μ is simply the logarithm of mean income
and s is standard deviation of logs of
income. (Notice again that s will be a
very small number.)
2b.
Compensatory increase in income derived
Now, we can
easily calculate the indifference condition, namely a condition such that is
the increase in mean income is just sufficient (from the welfare point of view)
to offset an increased dispersion of incomes, measured by s.
Thus, from
(2),
and
and the
condition becomes
We call this
compensatory
income change. It is the percentage increase in mean income needed to
offset (compensate), from the welfare point of view, a given increase in the
dispersion of (logs) of incomes. (Obviously, the reverse holds too: if s goes
down, compensatory income change will be negative.)
As equation
(3) shows, the compensatory income change is increasing in s. In other words,
if there is a given change in s (ds=given), the compensatory increase in mean
income is the greater, the greater the starting position s, that is the initial
dispersion of incomes. Thus, at higher levels of inequality—measured by
s—compensatory increases in mean income have to be progressively greater.
3.Gini and standard deviation of
lognormal income distribution
Now,
independently, we know that when incomes are lognormally distributed, Gini is related to the standard deviation of
incomes as follows
(4)
where Φ is a
cumulative distribution function of a normally distributed variable with the
mean = 0 and standard deviation = 1. For example if Gini = 0.5, then =0.75 which is the case if s=0.96. (Note again that s is the
standard deviation of logs of income.)
If we could
write out s explicitly as a function of
Gini, we could directly substitute s by Gini in equation (3) and thus directly
link compensatory income change to Gini. This is our objective but we
shall have to reach it in a roundabout way because it is hard (impossible?) to
write out s as an explicit function of Gini.
We have to
tease out numerically the nature of the relationship between s and Gini.
Figure 1 shows the relationship: we let Gini increase from 0 to 1 and
find the corresponding s’s
from equation (4). It is obvious from the Figure that Gini is concave in
s, that is that ever greater increases in s are needed to elicit a given
increase in Gini—or differently put, a given increase in Gini (at high Gini
values) implies ever greater increases in s.
Figure 1. The numerical relationship between standard deviation of
log of incomes and Gini
This means
that the trade-off between mean income and Gini is even sharper than the
trade-off between mean income and
standard deviation of logs (s) as given by (3).
As shown in Figure 1, up to approximately G of 0.5, the changes in s and
G are about equi-proportionate, and we can write approximately ds=K0 dG
where K=some constant. Thus, up to G≈0.5
Note that this still implies that compensatory
income change is increasing in initial
inequality (initial G). But at values of
Gini greater than 0.5, the compensatory income changes are even greater than those implied by this
last relationship because of the concavity of Gini with respect to s. At such high values of Gini, a given
percentage increase of s will move Gini by very little. Gini will be very
sluggish. Thus, at these high Gini
values, a given change in Gini will have to be compensated by even greater
increases in mean income.
In other
words, at very high levels of
inequality, we need huge (and ultimately infinite) increases in mean income to
offset further increases in Gini. This should be intuitively obvious: as Gini approaches 1, it will requires
enormous increases in mean income to keep the overall welfare unchanged simply
because more and more of total income will accrue to fewer and fewer people.
The welfare gains from income gains are minimal while welfare losses for those
who lose out are much larger. To balance off the two (gains and losses), we
need a very large increase in overall, and thus average, income.
4. What is compensatory income change
for a long-term increase in global inequality?
We can now
answer the original question: if global Gini had increased from about 0.55
around 1870 to 0.7 today, what is the
compensatory increase in average world income?
The standard deviations of log of incomes corresponding to the Ginis of
0.55 and 0.7 are respectively 1.075 and 1.471 (from equation 4). If we use equation (3)—which is indeed derived for
infinitesimal changes, but will be used here in the case of a discrete
change—we get
which means
that the compensatory mean income increase is 42.57 percent. Around 1870, the
mean income (GDP per capita) of the world was some $PPP 911. The compensatory
increase would have been about $PPP 388, that is the mean global income would
have to rise to about $PPP 1,300 for the overall average welfare to remain
unchanged. [1]
However, today’s GDP per capita is $PPP 6,200 or almost five times greater than
the compensatory income level would have to be.
So, within this framework, it is obvious that the average world welfare
must be much greater today than in 1870.
Incidentally.
it also shows why at Gini levels in excess of about 0.5, compensatory income
increases have to be (at times perhaps) inordinately high in order to keep
aggregate welfare unchanged.
5. How does it look in terms of Sen’s
index?
Sen’s
welfare index, interpreted as total welfare of a community, is defined as
It thus
provides a direct relationship between mean income and Gini. Using total differention of dw as before to
find the compensatory income change we obtain
The last
relationship provides a direct link between the change in Gini and compensatory
change in mean income. Are the results similar to what we have obtained
before? We readily see that at high
values of Gini, compensatory income increases (with a given dG) become greater.
Similarly, when G approaches 1, the compensatory income increases tends (like
in our case) toward very high values, even infinity. Using the same global data
as before, we find that the compensatory income increase which would have
kept Sen’s welfare index unchanged, is 0.33 or 33
percent. Thus with Sen’s index we get
that the result that, to offset global increase in inequality from 0.55 to 0.7,
mean global income had to go up by 33
percent, that is less than some 43 percent that we found earlier. Obviously, in
both cases, the overall mean welfare today must be significantly greater than
in 1870.
[1]
We normalize throughout by total population, i.e., do not take into account
population increase which may be valuable, in total welfare sense, by itself
(see Jean-Yves Duclos).
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.