While the world is witnessing global convergence (essentially
the catch up of Asia with the West), the debates about the origins of the Great Divergence—the take-off
of the West and absence of growth in the Rest—are going strong. I just finished
an excellent book ("Escaping poverty") by Peer Vries who reviews the origins of modern economic
growth and proposes his own theory on what made the West, and in particular,
Great Britain start the Industrial Revolution and China not.
Vries has two characteristics which are not abundant, in the
same person, among economists: erudition and common sense. Very often common
sense and cleverness, exhibited by more business-inclined types in economics,
go without much historical knowledge. But heavy erudition sometimes renders authors
other-worldly, a strange feature in a social scientist that economists are
supposed to be.
I would like to discuss Vries’s book under four headings:
organization of the book, his theory of why the Industrial Revolution happened
in England, his view why China’s chances to begin an industrial revolution were
“nil”, and (some) of his critiques of other economic historians.
Organization of the
book. Vries divides
the book in three parts. In the first,
he reviews all factors which, according to economists, are conducive to
economic growth in general; in the second part, he discusses each of these factors
as it applies to the explanation of the Industrial Revolution, and in the
conclusion, he …well…summarizes them again.
The causes of growth are nicely divided into direct causes, the
ones that we would readily put in the production function: geography and factor
endowments; the proximate causes: trade and innovations; and the “deep causes”:
institutions, state and culture.
The structure has certain advantages of symmetry, but I found
it a bit tedious. It taxes the patience of the reader and provokes some fatigue
because essentially the same issues (and even some sentences) are repeated in the
general and “applied” sections. I also think it is unfortunate that Vries has
not set up in a separate chapter his own views on the origins of the Great Divergence.
As it is, his views have to be pieced together from various parts of the book.
To this I turn next, and I hope to faithfully reflect Vries’ opinions.
Why did England take
off? I found Vries’
explanation very compelling, perhaps because it is also somewhat eclectic. But
the reality seldom obeys our abstract schemata. Vries agrees with Bob Allen’s
view that the key ingredients in British industrialization were expensive labor
and cheap energy and money. This led to labor-saving innovations which were at
the origin of the technological revolution. But England also had, Vries argues,
a very strong “infrastructal” state that until 1830 followed protectionist policies
and often manipulated tariffs and taxes to help domestic producers, engaging in
what would be today viewed as “industrial policy”. Furthermore, England had a
big government, high taxes, high government expenditures, “yuge” Navy, enormous
debt to GDP ratio, and extravagantly highly paid government officials. Externally,
the country pursued imperialist and mercantilist
policies. Finally, and quite importantly, workers became the proletariat who
had to go to the market to sell their labor (that is, lacked the cushion of working
on own plot of land), and labor force became “commodified”.
England, in this short sketch, presents four distinguishing features:
Favorable factor endowments
Capitalism: rational profit-making
and commodification of labor
Big government
Outside projection of
power (“fiscal-military, mercantilist and imperialist state”, p. 433).
It is the addition (appendage, as it were) of an acquisitive,
determined and big state that distinguishes Vries’ explanation from others which,
as he points out, present an idealized Smithian picture of a government of low
taxes, strong property rights, and tolerable administration of justice. His
views on the importance of the use of force in international trade (on the open
seas, “the distinction between peaceful, consensual trade and simple piracy was
often very thin if not simply non-existent”, p. 148) makes his views close to
Findlay and O’Rourke’s (whose work Vries cites very favorably) and even the world-system
theorists. But with the latter, he agrees only that mercantilism and imperialism
helped West’s take off but cannot explain it. Which brings us to why China has,
as Vries several times mentions, “nil” chance of starting the technological revolution.
Why China did not take
off? Here Vries is obviously
at odds with the California school as well as with dependency theorists (respectively, Pomerantz and
Frank) who believe that China had as great a likelihood, say, around 1750, of
becoming the first industrial power as did western Europe. Vries sees many
reasons why this was unlikely. Consider the four features that made England take
off: they are all reversed in the case of China. China’s labor was cheap,
energy and money were expensive. Chinese government was weak, paternalistic and
unable to collect taxes. China had no army to speak about and was not engaged
in military operations beyond its borders. And finally, production in China was
organized in family units: it was the land of household mode of production (p.
204), or as Marx would have said, petty commodity production. Thus, workers
could stay at home and work together with their families, often living cklose
to the subsistence level. What was lacking was the reserve Army of the unemployed
who in order to survive had to “feed” the capitalist engine in the West.
But while China was very unlikely to achieve a technological breakthrough,
it was an equally or more market-oriented society as the West, at least as far
as market for the consumption goods was concerned; China’s markets were more integrated
than European, it conducted greater amount of long-distance trade, and its government
was much smaller. So here we would, looking from a neoclassical angle, behold all
the ingredients that should help China grow (integrated market, small
government, low taxes). Yet they did
not. Qing China, in effect, in Vries’ rendering, sounds much more Smithian than
Britain (p. 354) but precisely because it was more Smithian it failed to
develop.
Critiques. As I already mentioned, Vries presents a rich, very erudite review of
an enormous literature and critiques a number of narratives that have either enjoyed
or still enjoy significant currency among economists. Let me mention, for lack
of space, but a few them.
Jared Diamond and Ian Morris are “savaged” for their
geographical determinism: “As general statements,
claims about challenges and responses [are mechanistic], and do not explain anything
at all” (p. 165).
Gregory Clark and Oded Galor with their views on the importance
of fertility behavior for human capital
formation and innovation cannot explain such seemingly anomalous development
where high increase in population does not produce more innovations, or decline
in fertility does not improve investment in skills: “unified growth theory has nothing
to offer historians” (p. 197).
Daron Acemoğlu and James Robinson start from an unproven assumption
that market is always good for growth and their “metanarrative is a stylized
generalization of a very...positive interpretation of modern history of Great
Britain and the USA” (p. 137). In addition
they never define “extractive” or “inclusive” institutions. David Landes as
well as Acemoğlu and Robinson “reproduce all the standard clichés when it comes
to Asian institutions” (p. 59).
The California school is just plain wrong on China’s level of
development being close to the European level prior to the take-off and Andre
Gunder Frank writes “with his usual lack of nuance and overdose of
self-assurance” (p. 340).
Peer Vries has written a great book from which one can learn
a lot, not solely to improve one’s understanding of the past but to stimulate
one’s thinking about the factors that make economies grow today.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.