My first Summer
book to read and review is Kate Raworth’s
very successful “Doughnut economics: Seven ways to think like the 21st-century economist”. It is an ambitious
book whose objective is to change the ways economists think and the economics
is framed in order to respond to the “limits to growth”. It thus reconsiders
the organization of the economy, from the financial sector, money creation, ownership
structure of companies to the distribution of assets. It also wrestles with the
“addiction” to economic growth, not only among the policy-makers but among most
of the population (that understandably want more things) and it finally envisages
a rich society with “zero growth”. The last term is avoided by Raworth by saying
she is agnostic about growth and by presenting future growth as undulating
around a stable level, with the economy at times going down and at times up “(“[we]
embrace growth without exacting it”, p. 270).
The book is probably
better than its competitors in the area. For example, Raworth’s discussion of
inequality where she argues for the equalization of endowments rather than expansion
of policies that redistribute current
income, makes lots of sense. Suggestions for the use of various incentives to
make companies more environment-friendly are also plausible. Perhaps even the imaginative
use of electronic currencies may help.
Yet the book
fails to convince for three reasons.
First, it
never faces squarely (or even indirectly) the fact that if everybody in the
world is to be “allowed” to have income level equal to the current median in
the rich countries, world GDP would have to increase three times—not accounting
for the rise in the world population. This is a fact for which Raworth has no
answer and thus prefers not to mention it. (For obviously, if one is against trebling
world GDP, one needs either to accept that half of the world population will continue
living in poverty, or to produce some evidence that carbon intensity of
production will suddenly plummet.)
Second, numerous
examples of companies and people who do innovative “green” things are listed (which
is quite useful) but their importance is never assessed. The reader is right, I
think, to feel that their importance is marginal and while progress is made, it
is minimal compared to what needs to happen.
Third, the
interpretation of the current phase of globalized capitalism is, in my opinion,
wrong. Rather than seeing it, as Raworth does, as becoming more cooperative and
“gentler”, it is more correct to see the inroads of commodification into our personal
lives (which we not only willingly accept but promote) as moving us further
toward a self-centered, money- and success-oriented society—that is, going exactly
in the opposite direction from that which Raworth favors.
I will illustrate
this last point with Raworth’s discussion of intrinsic vs. extrinsic
motivation. This last point (Chapter 3), where Raworth shows, based on empirical
studies, that extrinsic (money-driven) motivations may at times produce worse
outcomes than the use of non-cash motivation (emulation, social pressure etc.)
is, in my opinion, the best part of the book—but it is also the one where I disagree,
not with the arguments, but with Raworth’s interpretation of the current state
of the world and tacit forecasts for the future.
Raworth very
persuasively shows that working on intrinsic motivations may often be preferable
(measured in terms of hard-nosed efficiency) than using cash grants. I agree
with that (actually, I just follow the studies that show that) but I think that
the contemporary hyper-commercialized capitalism leads us more and more to value
only monetary incentives and to disregard others—even if the latter can produce
better outcomes. But to do so they have to be grounded into traditional social norms,
traditional hierarchy, social capital and the like, the very things which
globalized capitalism erodes daily. Thus I conclude that non-cash incentives, despite
their advantages in many situations, are doomed to extinction. Kate implicitly argues
the opposite: if they are better they should be used more. But by whom? What
are the social forces to promote them? Who has the incentive to do so? Is today’s
societies’ ethos compatible with them?
And here appears
the major weakness of the book. The world Kate has in mind is a world essentially
devoid of major social contradictions.
It often comes close to the world of Bastiat’s “universal harmonies”. In many instances, Kate writes in the first-person
plural, as if the entire world had the same “objective”: so “we” have to make
sure the economy does not exceed the natural bounds of the Earth’s “carrying capacity”,
“we” have to keep inequality within the acceptable limits, “we” have an
interest in a stable climate, “we” need the commons sector. But in most of the real
world economics and politics, there is no “we” that includes 7.3 billion
people. Different class and national interests are fighting each other.
The same
“we-ism” is apparent when Raworth calls for deemphasis (“agnosticism”) of economic
growth. I have already mentioned that the world’s poor get a short shift, but
the argument why growth in the rich countries should cease, and how to go about
it, is also presented in a most confused fashion (and perhaps there is no way
to present it better). Raworth acknowledges that economic growth is needed to soften
distributional conflicts, to maintain democracy, as well as for people’s subjective
happiness but she fails to provide any persuasive arguments how a new “no-growth” regime will come about (who is going to vote for it?) nor
how it would solve these real issues. “We” should somehow be magically transformed
from acquisitive and money-grubbing beings, traits which the system itself
encourages in us, to people, who under the same system, are rather indifferent to
how well we do compared to others, and do not really care about wealth and income.
Short of
magic, this is not going to happen. It then becomes apparent that Raworth’s book is a book of miracles, as well
as why in such a world of miracles, the real “miracle” which is Chinese growth that
has pulled out of abject poverty some 700 million people goes all but unmentioned.
The reason is that poverty was eliminated
by “dirty” growth that has polluted Chinese cities and the countryside,
disrupted Arcadian idyll between man/woman and nature—and yet made the lives of
millions incomparably better.
Raworth’s
ideal world seems to be the one that we find in Giotto’s paintings of St
Francis, but it is not the world we inhabit. In an attempt to convince us that “other
worlds are possible” Raworth uses the example of an Indian tribe in northern
Manitoba which a couple of centuries ago responded to an increase in price by
providing fewer goods.
Rather than proposing
the economics for the 21st century, Raworth’s book brings us back to
the imaginary world of the early Christendom. Perhaps that such imaginary
people were then “thriving” (a term Raworth uses at least 50 times in the book),
but the real world even in those times was different: it was the world of
Augustus and Spartacus, burned temples and fortunes made through violence.
Exactly like ours. Except that we are richer. Which is a good thing.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.