Sometimes it’s
useful to put symbolic dates on when a different era begins. The end of Thatcherism,
it could be argued, came
on July 10 in the then PM-candidate speech by Theresa May. It was perhaps appropriate
that another woman, a Tory Prime Minister, would be credited with the ending of
Thatcherism. The key words, which immediately attracted attention (see
also Philip Stevens in today’s “Financial Times”) were not those about inequality (which has become a common place these
days) but about the changes in the
internal structure of capitalism: reintroduction of workers’ and consumers’ representatives
on management boards, limits on the executive pay, reduction of job insecurity
for the young people and much greater access to top jobs for those coming from
less privileged backgrounds.
For the
first time since the late 1970s (at the top level of policy-making), we are
back to the issues of reforms in the way capitalism functions rather than discussing
the ways in which the external environment would be made more market friendly. In
essence, this is a confession that “civilizing” capitalism cannot be done only
“externally” by relying on the “harmony of private interests” but that the
state has a bigger role that goes beyond ensuring the protection of property
rights, taxation and redistribution.
The past 35
years have shown that the neo-liberal conception of capitalism, combined with
its global reach, has increased inequality to often unsustainable levels, left
large segments of the population in the rich world without significant increase
in real income and with heightened insecurity, and brought populist policies
with a vengeance. Theresa May was thus right to highlight that the Brexit vote
was at least as much a vote about the British economic system and the role of
the political elite as it was about Brussels.
It may be
too early to see exactly how things may change but I can imagine the main changes
in three areas.
The first
area is economic policy of the advanced countries. The key disagreement there
is between those who believe that the current economic dissatisfaction and the populist
backlash are the product of the 2007-08 crisis and those who call for more
fundamental changes. The first group believes
that the problems will vanish once Western economies go back to growing at 2-3
percent per year and reduce unemployment (as the US has already done). I think
they minimize what has happened in the meantime and lack any ideas how to address the structural
weaknesses of capitalism. This is where Theresa May steps in by arguing for structural
changes (the structure is meant here as the way capitalism works).
I have
argued in my “Global Inequality” that taxation of current income seems to have
reached the maximum that the rich countries’ electorates can tolerate.
Therefore, reduction of inequality, “empowerment of ordinary people” and
widening of opportunities have to be accomplished through a change in the
distribution of both financial and human assets. This implies deconcentration of
capital ownership (which in all rich countries attains almost unfathomable Gini
levels of 0.85-0.9) and much fairer access to high-quality levels of education (and
thus to high pay) to those born in poorer families.
On the first
point, it is often said that the middle class has no interest to acquire
capital mostly because of volatility in its returns. But if as much ingenuity had
been deployed in finding fiscal ways to make diversification of ownership
appealing to more people as it was invested in making the rich create tax loopholes, one would be able, in the medium
term, to reduce the current extreme concentration of wealth.
The second area where I see the need for major changes is in development. It has always been the case that the development economics (including development economics as applied by major international organization) has moved together with economic ideology waves in rich countries. In full ideological lock-step with neo-liberalism, the past several decades in development were dominated by efforts to “improve the economic framework” (make regulation lighter, allow faster registration of enterprises, reduce government red tape etc.)
While many
of these policies made sense they had two significant shortcomings: they exaggerated
(again fully in agreement with similar policies pursued in advanced economies)
the ability of the free market to spontaneously produce desirable outcomes, and
they shifted the role of international agencies toward the “soft” areas, from gender and sexual-orientation equality to “transparency”,
to the detriment of actual investments
in roads, infrastructure, telecommunication, electricity generation. Indeed,
the “framework goods” are important, but they are not all that matters.
Moreover, this emphasis led to millions of hours of (wasted) work and thousands
of papers that just repeated nostrums, creating NGOs they preyed on foreign and
their citizens’ money to pay themselves hefty fees under the pretense of doing
the work of development. Such lop-sided emphasis has made organizations like
the World Bank consistently less important players in the area of development.
The more robust Chinese approach, reflected in its policy in Africa, and now in
the new Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank has given, one would hope, a good
jolt to the old development institutions to move back to the harder areas of development,
and not solely on organizing conferences with “stakeholders”.
The third change
that is coming regards immigration policies. Here Europe is the primary
battlefield because the issue of migration has been conflated with the issue of
terrorism. This is an unprecedented development. Whether we look at the European
migrations in the 19th or 20th century to the Unites
States and Latin America, Indian labor moving to the West Indies, or the Chinese
moving to East Asia, migration problems were seen as those of assimilation,
jobs and wages for the native labor, but never as issues of personal security.
(A possible, small exception to that is the view, briefly held in the United
States, that South-European immigrants at the close of the 19th century
were disproportionally likely to be anarchists.)
Major
adjustments in European countries to accept more of non-European migrants are already
taking place. Even if Angela Merkel cannot go back to what was already done and
expel the migrants Germany accepted last year, it is clear that no such wave
will be willingly accepted In Europe any time soon. (It does not guarantee that
another such wave may not materialize though—but it will not be welcomed.)
But creating
a fortress Europe is difficult and runs counter the economic interests of an aging
Europe that needs fresh labor from Africa and Asia. This is why I have argued
in “Global inequality” for a change in the approach to citizenship which is currently
seen as an almost inevitable end-point for any individual who makes it to a EU country
(or the United States and Canada). Instead of that, different levels of
residency, including temporary jobs (that were originally the idea behind the German
Gastarbeiter system) with the obligation to return to the country of origin, should
become generalized. Citizenship rights should be divorced from the right to
work in a country.
If this line
of thinking is correct, we should expect in the next decade a major redefinition
of how capitalism works in the advanced societies, a redefinition of the role
of international development organizations, and a redefinition of what it means
to be a migrant and a citizen. This should, in principle, allow the rich countries
to continue their key role in globalization and to be rid of this paradoxical position,
where they, the spiritus movens of globalization, seem now most afraid of it.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.