In a paper that I am writing with Boško Mijatoviċ on the real wage in the 19th
century Serbia (see
the first draft here), we deal with an interesting and not novel problem. In
a society where 90 percent of the population lives in the countryside and all farmers
cultivate their own (small) landholding, and there is no landlessness, how do
you industrialize?
All the contemporary evidence points to the fact that peasants
were not at all keen to move to cities and work for a wage. Since there was no
landlessness very few people were pushed by poverty to look for city jobs.
Political parties which strongly (and understandably) represented peasantry further
limited mobility of labor by guaranteeing homestead (3.5 ha of land, house,
cattle and the implements) which could not be alienated, neither in the case of
default on the loan nor in the case of overdue taxes.
This situation was very typical for the late industrializers
in South-East Europe. Greece, Bulgaria and Serbia were all overwhelmingly
agricultural with small peasant landholdings and no landlessness. All displayed
slow or arrested capitalist development and half-hearted urbanization. The reason
was simple: farmers had no incentive to move from being self-employed to being hired
labor. And who would prefer to switch from being one’s own boss and dependent perhaps
only on the elements to become a hired hand, working six days a week all year round,
in “satanic mills”?
The issue is noted by Francis Fukuyama (among others) in “Political
Order and Political Decay”. He explains slow industrial development in Greece
(and he could have readily added Serbia and Bulgaria) by political clientelism which
in his views stemmed from premature democratization, that is, before programmatic
and not clientilistic political parties could be formed. But he fails to see
the economic origin of the problem: lack
of incentive to move to cities.
The question is, how do you industrialize under such
conditions? Reluctance of peasants, whenever they had their own land, to become
industrial workers has been discussed (Gerschenkron, Polanyi). In England they
had to be literally chased from land through enclosures; in France, the process was much more
overdrawn and took a century; in Germany, Poland and Hungary, large estates owned
by nobility and consequent landlessness did the job. In Russia, it was bloody
and occurred through forced collectivization.
Which introduces the following interesting topic. Suppose as
a counterfactual that the October Revolution never took place, as it seemed most
likely until the very day when it occurred, and that Russia, after the March revolution,
became a democracy. Tsarism was overthrown, the elections of the Constituent
Assembly were held in December 1917, and the largest party in the new Duma
(later disbanded by the Bolsheviks) were Social-Revolutionaries (SR) that, combining
their Russian and Ukrainian branches, held about 50% of the seats. (Bolsheviks
got 24% of the vote.)
SRs were the party of the peasantry. By 1918 after the forced
seizures of large estates, the land reverted
to peasants, and the bulk of them acquired their own plots. Landlessness was relatively
small. (I have seen somewhere the figures
from the early 1920 given by, I think, Bukharin or Zinoviev but cannot find
them now.)
How do you industrialize then? Peasants are quite happy to
stay on land; SRs, who depend for their parliamentary majority on peasantry, might
have passed the laws similar to the ones passed in the late 19th
century Serbia guaranteeing peasant property from creditors or the state. Why
would under these conditions peasants move to Moscow or St Petersburg to become
wage workers unless they got a much higher wage –most unlikely—than was their net
marginal return from farming? So unlike in the Lewis model of development with an
infinite supply of labor here we deal with development, or rather attempted development,
with close to zero new supply of labor.
Could high export taxes be imposed on Russian/Ukrainian grain
to provide savings which would be invested in industrial development (a policy followed
by Peronists in Argentina)? It is hard to imagine that a party (SRs) that did
not depend on industrial proletariat but on peasantry would have done that. You
thus quickly reach an impasse. To develop industrially, you need landless
peasants looking for city jobs. But in a society where peasants own farms and
their parties control government, there is no incentive nor desire to move to cities.
Stasis, or equilibrium of sorts, ensues.
Now, going back to what really happened in Russia, we see
better what was the problem faced by Bolsheviks. The war that Stalin launched
on peasantry in 1928 and which resulted in at least an estimated six million
deaths from famine and destroyed the Soviet agriculture for the entire period
of the existence of the USSR was to some extent in the cards from the very
moment that the March revolution happened. Russia could have more easily become
industrial and capitalist with the pre-1917 large landed estates and the attendant landless
peasantry which gravitated toward cities for jobs. But once small land owners became
dominant, the (non-violent) road to industrialization was either blocked or had
to be very long.
The process whereby agricultural economies industrialized was
wrenching. The displacement and unhappiness of the population dragged into
industrial centers through either empty stomachs or outright terror was incomparable
in its human costs to today’s similar transfer of labor from manufacturing to
services (or to unemployment). The transformation in the underlying economic structure
is never easy but it seems to me that the one from the fresh air and freedom of
own farm to being a cog in a huge soiled machine of industrialization was the
most painful.
--------------
--------------
PS.
Paul Klebnikov in a very detailed Ph D dissertation on Russian agriculture before the World War I, quotes (p.
32) a social democratic politician A. Maslov who argued that only industrialization
can raise incomes in Russia: “one of two things must happen: either the
development of the manufacturing industry with the proletarianization of a
certain portion of the population, or complete backwardness and even a decline
in the productive forces of the country."
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.