You think it is a contradiction in terms, a paradox. But you
are wrong: we are used to think in pure categories while life is much more complex;
and paradoxes do exist in real life. China is indeed a country of Hayekian
communism.
Nowhere is, I think, wealth and material success more openly
celebrated than in China. Perhaps it was stimulated by the 40th
anniversary of the opening up which is this year, but more fundamentally, I
think, it is stimulated by the most successful economic development in
history. Rich entrepreneurs are celebrated
in newspapers, television, conferences. Their wealth and rags-to-riches stories
are held as examples for all. Ayn Rand would feel at home in this environment.
So would Hayek: an incredible amount of energy and discovery was unleashed by
the changes that transformed lives of 1.4 billion people, twice as many as the combined
populations of the “old” EU-15 and the United States. People discovered
economic information that was inaccessible or unknown before, organized in a Schumpeterian
fashion new combinations of capital and labor, and created wealth on an almost unimaginable
scale (certainly, unimaginable for anyone who looked at China in 1978).
At a
large banquet in Beijing, we were presented first-hand stories of five Chinese
capitalists who started from zero (zilch! nada! ) in the 1980s, and became dollar
billionaires today. One spent years in countryside during the Cultural Revolution,
another was put in prison for seven years for “speculation”, the third made his
“apprentissage” of capitalism, as he candidly said, by cheating people in East
Asia (“afterwards I learned that if I really wanted to become rich, I should not
cheat; cheating is for losers”). Hayek would have listened to these stories,
probably transfixed. And what news would
he have loved better than to read in today’s Financial Times that the Marxist
society at the Peking University was disbanded because of its support of
striking workers in the Special Economic Zone of Shenzhen.
But there is one thing where Hayek went wrong. These
incredible personal (and societal) successes were achieved under the rule of a
single party, Communist Party of China. Celebration of wealth comes naturally
to Marxists. Development, widespread education, gender equality, urbanization, and
indeed faster growth than under capitalism, were the rationale, and sources of
legitimacy, of communist revolutions as they took place in the less developed
world. Lenin said so; Trotsky confirmed it when he canvassed for large-scale industrialization;
Stalin implemented it: “We are fifty or a hundred years behind the advanced
countries. We must make good this difference in ten years. Either we do it, or
we shall be crushed”.
I remember, as a precocious high-school student in Yugoslavia,
how I scanned the newspapers for the indicators of industrial growth. Since Yugoslavia
was then among the fastest growing economies in the world, I was deeply disappointed
when the monthly growth rate (annualized) would fall below ten percent. I thought
ten percent was the normal growth rate of communist economies: why would you care
to become communist if you would not grow faster than under capitalism?
So the celebration of growth—new roads, new super fast trains,
new housing complexes, new well-lit avenues and orderly schools—comes naturally
to communists. Not any less than to Hayekian entrepreneurs. (As an exercise in
this, read Neruda’s beautiful memoirs Confeso Que He Vivido where he exudes enormous pleasure at
seeing Soviet-built dams.) The difference though is that the Hayekinans celebrate
private success which also helps society move forward; in communism, success
too was supposed to be socialized.
But this did not happen. Collectivist efforts worked for a
decade or two but eventually growth fizzled out and the efforts flagged.
Cynicism reigned supreme. It was left to China and to Deng Xiaoping to stumble
(in the immortal phrase of Adam Ferguson) on a combination where the rule of
the communist party would be maintained but full freedom of action, and social encomium,
would be given to individual capitalists. They would work, become rich, enrich
many others in the process, but the reins of political power would firmly remain
in the hands of the communist party. Capitalists will provide the engine and
the fuel, but the party will hold the steering wheel.
Would things be even better if the political power too was in
the hands of capitalists? This is doubtful. They might have used it to recreate
the Nanjing government of the 1930s, venal, weak and incompetent. They would
not work hard but would use political power to maintain their economic privileges.
It is one of the key problems of US capitalism today that the rich increasingly
control the political process and thus skew economic incentives away from
production and competition into creation and preservation of monopolies. Much
worse would likely have happened in China. It is precisely because the political
sphere was largely insulated from the economic sphere that capitalists could be
safely kept busy with production, and at arm’s length (as far as possible
because the party is exposed to growing corruption) from the politics.
How did China stumble on this combination? There may be many
reasons including millennial tradition of being run by imperial bureaucracies, the
historical alliance --even if it got unraveled—between the Communist patty and Sun
Yat-sen’s KMT (an alliance the like of which never existed elsewhere in the
communist world)—but one cannot but ask oneself, could it have happened
elsewhere too? Perhaps. Lenin’s New Economic Policy was not much different from
Chinese policies of the 1980s. But Lenin saw NEP as a temporary concession to capitalists—because
he believed that socialism was more progressive and thus “scientifically” generated
higher growth. Perhaps it is only the failures of the Great Leap Forward and the
chaos of the Cultural Revolution that chastened Chinese leadership and convinced
Deng and others that private initiative was more “progressive” than social planning
and state-owned enterprises. Lenin could not have seen that. It was too early.
I also wondered what Stalin would have made of China. He probably
would have been glad that his name is still enshrined in the official pantheon.
(In a large bookstore in downtown Beijing, the first row of books are
translations of Marxist classics: Marx himself, Engels, Lenin..and Stalin. Very
few people look at them. The next rows that display books on wealth management,
finance economics, stock market investments etc. are much more popular.) Stalin
would have been impressed by Chinese growth; by the extensive power of the
state and the country (for sure, no longer a country to which he could send his
advisors to help it technologically), by the party’s ability to control in a
very sophisticated and unobtrusive manner the population.
Stalin would have loved economic success and the military power
that comes with it, but would have probably been shocked by private wealth. It
is hard seeing him coexist with Jack Ma. Hayek’s reaction would have been the
opposite: he would have been delighted that his claims about the spontaneous
market order have been vindicated in a most emphatic fashion, but would have
failed to understand that this was possible only under the rule of a communist
party.
No one would have been left indifferent by the most successful
economic story ever. And no one would have fully understood it.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.