Under the influence of
Amartya Sen, we have been “nudged” towards
a reassessment of the relative merits of “The theory of moral sentiments “
(TMS) and “The Wealth of Nations” (WN). Sen has done a lot to bring Smith’s early
work out of relative obscurity where it was consigned by two centuries of
success of the Wealth of Nations and to remind us of Smith’s reputation of a
moral philosopher rather, or in addition to, being the founder of modern political
economy.
Having recently reread WN
(previously I had read only the first two books), I have no doubt that the
Wealth of Nations is a vastly superior and more mature work. It is not, I
think, because I am an economist and scarcely able to judge TMS. It is just
that the underlying atmospherics in the two books are very different. In TMS,
Smith, still in thrall, I think, to his professorial role of a moral (and to some
extent religious or theistic) teacher, tries hard to put a bright gloss over the
vicissitudes of the world. His rejection of Mandeville’s philosophy in the
latter part of TMS is contrived and weak despite a strong language used (“pernicious
system”, “ingenious sophistry”) and one senses a basic discomfort with the
rejection of something that Smith has come, I believe reluctantly, to approve of, or
at least to see some merit in. This will become clearer in the Wealth of
Nations.
The atmospherics of the
WN are entirely different. Not only is it a work of a more mature
person (Smith was 53 when the book was published), but the atmosphere there reminded me of Nirad Chaudhri’s definition
of human’s third age as one of “stern, almost exultant despair”. For in the Wealth
in Nations there are no “good guys”. It is almost entirely the “world of
tyranny of evil men” (as Samuel Jackson would say in “Pulp Fiction”).
The government comes, of course, for special criticism: its rapacity
in putting up high tariffs, its foolishness in following mercantilist policies,
its pettiness in constraining the system of “natural liberty”, its attempts to decide
where people should live (the law of settlement, a hukou-like system was then in existence in Britain), its myriad
rules and vexations are dissected with righteous anger.
Next to it in terms of “badness” is aristocracy:
”Entails are thought necessary for maintaining this exclusive privilege of the
nobility to the great offices and honours of their country; and that order
having usurped one unjust advantage over the rest of their fellow-citizens,
lest their poverty should render it ridiculous, it is thought reasonable that
they should have another” (Book 3; Ch. 2, p. 491).
But businessmen are no better. As soon as
they are given half a chance, perhaps just after having gotten rid of some particularly
nefarious government regulation, they are back to plotting how to “restrain”
the market, to pay suppliers less, destroy competitors, cheat workers (see today’s IT
companies, Walmart, Amazon). In the famous quote, “people of the same trade seldom meet together, even
for merriment and diversion, but the conversation ends in a conspiracy against
the public, or in some contrivance to raise prices” (Book 1, Ch. 8).
In their mad
ambition, they try to rule the world (see Davos): “…the
mean rapacity, the monopolizing spirit of merchants and manufacturers, who
neither are, nor ought to be, the rulers of mankind” (Book 4, Ch. 3, p. 621). Short
of the world they try to rule countries: companies of merchants (the British
and the Dutch East India Companies) grew immensely rich by mismanaging and
exploiting India and Indonesia: “The
government of an exclusive company of merchants is, perhaps, the worst of all
governments for any country whatever” (Book 4, Ch. 7, p. 722).
And
their profits are often a price for general impoverishment: “Have the exorbitant profits of the merchants
of Cadiz and Lisbon augmented the capital of Spain and Portugal? Have they
alleviated the poverty, have they promoted the industry of those two beggarly
countries?” (Book 4, Ch. 7, p. 779).
Businessmen
depend on lobbyists and politicians. Those who support them (read K Street and
Mass Avenue in Washington DC) will be praised: “The Member of Parliament who
supports every proposal for strengthening this monopoly is sure to acquire not
only the reputation of understanding trade, but great popularity and influence
with an order of men whose numbers and wealth render them of great importance” (Book
4, Ch.2, p. 595).
Those who try to oppose their drive for monopoly
profits will be destroyed:
“If he opposes them, on the contrary,
and still more if he has authority enough to be able to thwart them, neither
the most acknowledged probity, nor the highest rank, nor the greatest public
services can protect him from the most infamous abuse and detraction, from
personal insults, nor sometimes from real danger, arising from the insolent
outrage of furious and disappointed monopolists. (Book 4, Ch. 2, p. 592).
Are “do-gooders” and religious orders (read
NGOs) any better? They are treated with implacable irony: “The late resolution
of the Quakers in Pennsylvania to set at liberty all their negro slaves, may satisfy us that their number cannot be very great” (Book
3, Ch 2, p. 496); or “I have never known much good done by those
who affected to trade for the public good. It is an affectation, indeed, not
very common among merchants, and very few words need be employed in dissuading
them from it” (Book 3, Ch. 2, p. 572).
Adventurers and soldiers who conquered
colonies attracted by the promise of quick gain (see military “contractors”
today) “commit[ed] with impunity every sort of injustice in those remote
countries” (Book 3, Ch. 7, p. 795). Led by their selfishness they destroyed a
great occasion for the beneficial encounter of two civilizations: “The savage
injustice of the Europeans rendered an event, which ought to have been
beneficial to all, ruinous and destructive to several of those unfortunate
countries” (Book 4, Ch. 1, p. 563).
Human selfishness, rapacity, need for pillage
crosses places and times: the crusaders were “the most destructive frenzy that
ever befell the European nations” and they were spurred on by the merchant
republics of Venice, Genoa and Pisa for whom the crusade “was a source of
opulence” (Book 3, Ch. 3, p. 513).
There is no end of “badness”.
Even Smith’s most famous invention (the
invisible hand) takes place despite the
natural selfishness of men (“he intends only his own gain”). Note that through the invisible
hand, we fulfill a project which was not part of our original design, i.e., our
original intention was selfish but we could not satisfy it except by catering
to the needs of others. And of course we do not count on “the benevolence
of the butcher…but [on] his regard for own interest”. We do not count on
butcher’s benevolence because Smith knows that that benevolence is not there,
while we can be sure that self-interest is.
Market and the invisible
hand indeed turn out to be the almost miraculous contraptions that transform this
landscape of hard men, inured to bleakness, pursuit of self-interest and
cheating, into a tolerably civilized society where people, on surface at least,
treat each other with consideration. But, I think, there is no doubt to anyone who
has read the Wealth of Nations that this is only a veneer. Once it cracks, we are quickly back in the
animal kingdom, as we indeed got there during wars, colonial conquests or
crusades. And this is perhaps an additional, strong, reason for the importance
of market economy, commerce and general economic accoutrements of civilization
which. making use of our worst instincts, transform them into a tolerable or
respectful behavior. I think that by the time he wrote the Wealth of Nations Smith
must have come to agree with Mandeville about private vices and public virtue.
All page numbers are from "The Wealth of Nations", Bantam Classic, 2003; edited with notes and marginal summary by Edwin Cannan; preface by Alan B. Krueger.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.