For the centenary of the World War I, many new books
were published. The ones that I have read, especially Margaret McMillan’s “The War
that Ended Peace”, were so disappointing and superficial that I remembered the
one that I read in parts, some ten years ago: Niall Ferguson’s “The Pity of
War.” It was a good idea. It is indeed a book worth reading, especially for an economist
because (unlike other books on WW1) it deals extensively with economic issues.
But
it is also an unusual book. Although well-written and erudite, it shows all the defects of somebody who, perhaps in order to attract attention, is dead-set to
be revisionist, nor in one of two areas, but in most. And when on top of it, it is heavily
influenced by an ideology which is a combination of British imperialism (yet very
heavily critical of British policies prior to the War), empathy for the German
aristocracy except when it comes to post-War economic management (where Germany
is shown to have been able to pay reparations—but there the dislike of Keynes
seems to dominate all other concerns), and a strong dislike of anything that
smacks of Marxism, well, one could say that we are clearly not in
the presence of an ordinary book.
The
subtitle “Explaining World War I” is misleading because the book practically
does not deal at all with the Eastern Front. Russia, Austria-Hungary, Serbia, Turkey appear
at most in 2-3% of the text. Ferguson’s knowledge of Russian sources is clearly
non-existent, and there is no description of the war on the Eastern front, not even in the cases of such obvious
and well-known interdependencies of the two fronts as in the disastrous Russian
offensive of August 1914 conducted at the express demand of the Western Allies to
relieve German pressure on the French. Thus, the book is to all intents and
purposes a story of the war between UK,
France and Germany. But not nearly of the whole First World War.
The
revisionist discussion of most of the points follows a rather interesting approach
where the standard point of view is convincingly presented, then the
alternative (rebuttal) is set up, and then gradually, in many cases, the
weaknesses of the alternative, even if unacknowledged, become transparent. So,
in some strange ways, Ferguson often provides lots of ammunition to the reader
to reject Ferguson’s own revisionist position.
On
the positive side of the ledger, Ferguson is an excellent writer, has read an
enormous number of contemporary books, from poetry to philosophy, has a very
good knowledge of British and German sources (less so of the French, and practically
none of the Russian) and, unusually for a general historian, has a very good command
and interest in economics. Moreover, the
book is—because of the unusual approach whereby one’s theses are often undermined
in the presentation—much less revisionist than it seems at first, and probably
less than Ferguson originally intended it to be. This, perhaps accidental,
even-handedness is definitely a plus.
I
would go, point by point, over some of the revisionist issues, focusing more on
the ones where Ferguson deals with economics.
1) The war might not have happened at all. But after
reading Ferguson’s own discussion of one upon another contemporary bestseller calling
for, or discussing the future war, in fiction or in non-fiction, in all future belligerents’
countries; Ferguson’s multiple references to the pervasive militaristic and
jingoistic culture of the time; and the data on the rising military budgets
during the entire two decades prior to the war, it is hard to see how a war, whether
in 1914 or 1919 or 1922, could not have happened. It was just a matter of time:
like a Russian roulette it eventually had to fire.
2)
The war could have happened between a very different sets of powers. Here the argument
is that England and Germany had no irreconcilable conflict. This is one of the
key points of the book, and it is probably right if one could abstract from
more than a century of British policy whose aim was not to allow the emergence of
a single dominant power on the Continent.
Germany, Ferguson writes, willed the war because she was afraid of own financial
and military weakness. Power of federal states limited the ability to increase
central spending on the military; in the Reichstag, Social-Democrats were against it, and
internationally, greater borrowing led to the rising costs reflected in the widening
bond yield gap between UK and Germany (p. 135). Time was working against Germany:
hence a preemptive war against Russia, and if need be, France (pp. 33, 100). (Thus,
on where the main responsibility for the war lies, Ferguson is no revisionist.)
England, however, is responsible for
making this purely continental war into a World War. Edward Grey, the British foreign
minister, is (with Keynes) the main villain of the book. Grey wanted a war, Ferguson
writes, due to some nebulous obligation to help France, while a much smarter position
would have been for the UK to have stayed out and allowed Germany to create a “European
Union” which would not, ultimately, be a competitor to England. Discussion of this
counter-factual would take us too far, so I leave it here as presented by
Ferguson.
3)
There was no popular enthusiasm for the war. But the evidence against this
dominant view (buttressed by the throngs of millions in Berlin, London, Vienna, St Petersburg and
Paris) are just a few meager examples. Most people, even on Ferguson’s own
telling, enthusiastically supported the war when it was declared. He
acknowledges that parts of German SDs and Russian Bolsheviks, were the lonely
voices who voted against war credits. But he disingenuously rebuffs Hitler’s well-known
war enthusiasm expressed in his letters (and obviously shared by millions) by quoting a much more level-headed diary entry from an
English conscript written in…1915 (p. 175). Well, surely, by 1915 most of the enthusiasm
has evaporated.
4)
German economic mobilization of resources was no less successful than English.
This part is, I think, pretty well argued and substantiated. Germany increased government
spending and use of material and human resources no less successfully than Britain.
But since (1) it was economically weaker
(contrast German wealth with vast British gold reserves and foreign assets), (2)
its capital market was more shallow, and (3) it could not borrow abroad (although
it did so in New York until the US entered the war) and (4) could not raise taxes
due to the political power of its big business,
Germany ultimately had to resort to inflation. This led to price
controls, shortages, monetary overhang etc., all of which spread instability
and demoralized the “domestic front.” This was the key reason why Germany lost
the war in the Fall of 1918. Ferguson’s explanation for the famous “stab in the
back” is entirely economic, and moreover, to a large extent driven by domestic socio-economic
relations: power of the big business.
In matters of efficiency in conducting the war, Central powers
did better: they killed more soldiers and civilians than the Allies (Allies
include Russians), and spent much less money doing it. They were, in other
words, more efficient in the killing per unit of cost. Ferguson’s data there are
pretty compelling: Central powers killed 4.9 million people for a total cost of
$61b; the allies killed 3.3 million people for a total cost of $147b. Cost per
killed: Allies $44,000, central powers $12,000 (pp. 294, 337, passim). The problem was: Central powers
were economically weaker than the Allies, and their social structure was more
ossified (somebody else than Ferguson would have said “reactionary”).
5)
The Versailles reparations were not exceedingly punitive and they were not the reason
for Germany’s disastrous economic policy. While in the rest of the book, Ferguson
credits German economic management, here he comes in with a withering criticism. The reason economic
management was wrong was because Germans decided to pretend that paying the reparations
was impossible and used a two-pronged strategy to show it. First, by devaluing
the Reichsmark to boost exports in order to create trade surpluses (with which
to pay the reparations), they were in reality aiming to undercut English and
French exports, and show to the Allies, or at least to their exporters, that it
was not in their own interest that Germany should pursue such “beggar-thy-neighbor”
policy. It was a shrewd, albeit perhaps
too clever by half, strategy. From today’s vantage point of the Euro crisis, it
is delightful to read a German industrialist state in 1921 that “our good fortune, in the midst of misfortune, is our poor currency,
which enables us to export on a large scale” (p. 412).
The
second approach was to let inflation (already stimulated by devaluation) degenerate
into hyperinflation. The reduction of real value of domestic debt arranged workers and trade unions as
well as big business and creditors in general. In addition, the government
objective was to create an “organized havoc” and wave in front of the Allies
the specter of an imminent Communist revolution. The threat of Communism was then to be used to exact easier terms from the French
and the British.
Ferguson
thus makes two key economic points: reparations could have been paid and disastrous
economic policy was consciously pursued. Now, for those who know Ferguson’s antipathy
for Keynes (“a ‘soi-disant’ conscientious objector”, p 327), Keynes not surprisingly comes in for a
very special critique on both counts. Keynes wielded influence with the Germans
(the famous Melchior comes to mind, although it is unclear who influenced whom),
and convinced them not only that the Versailles terms were too harsh (Germans
needed little convincing on that) but that this view of inequity of Versailles,
in light of Keynes’ international reputation, will come to be shared by many in
the West. Then he “egged” Germans on to follow irresponsible policies until the
West yielded. All the while Keynes thought that inflation would be
controllable. When he realized that “controlled“ inflation necessary to increase
German exports and scare the Allies was sliding into hyperinflation, it was too
late. So Keynes failed to follow his own
warning regarding the destructive effects of hyperinflation made in “The Economic
Consequences of the Peace.” No one in Ferguson’s view did more damage than Keynes
in that respect. Keynes was both wrong and utterly irresponsible.
And
since Ferguson argues (rather fancifully) that German hyperinflation in 1920’s made
the 1929-33 depression in Germany particularly severe (“the inflation [in 1921]
was responsible for the onset and particular severity of the 1929-33 Slump in
Germany”, p. 426), then there is but one step from blaming Keynes to have been responsible
from bringing the Nazis to power. Ferguson never says it in so many words, but the implication is unmistakable.
The
book often presents excellent data on debt, currency circulation, interests rates,
output, real wages etc. All of the data are useful, and the reader will be grateful
to Ferguson for having combined in one place, and probably “harmonized”, all
the essential macro data for UK, France, Germany, Russia and Italy (and a few
other countries). But in some parts of the book (and nowhere more than in a mercifully short section
on the counter-factual German economic policy 1919-1923), the text is almost illegible
because of too much back-and-forth among the numbers, mixing up, in the same
paragraph or even a sentence, the actual outcomes with possible outcomes or with
Ferguson’s preferred outcomes. It is also odd for such a well-researched book that
on the issue of reparations no mention is made of Keynes’ nemesis, Etienne
Mantoux and his detailed “La paix calomniée.” There Ferguson could have found 400
pages of meticulous detail and calculations to support his anti-Keynes’ stance.
(Although Mantoux’s point was rather that reparations were not so unreasonable,
not what economic policy Germany should have followed.)
Ferguson’s
discussion of the Russian revolution is perfunctory and minimalist. In keeping with
his willful ignorance of any other front but the western, the October
Revolution hardly exists at all and the Brest-Litovsk peace agreement is
mentioned…twice. The discussion is often prejudiced too. While Ferguson usefully
compares the number of victims of the Russian Civil War and Russian losses in
the First World War proper (the former 1.2 million people vs. 1.8 for in WW1),
and in additions mentions perhaps as many as 5 million who died from hunger
during the Civil War (pp. 389-90), Western military intervention against the
Bolsheviks is non-existent. Neither does he discuss the fact stated in the book
that the victims among the Reds were 3 times more numerous than among the Whites
(must have had something to do with the executions of POWs and hostages). He presents
Trotsky as an unmitigated monster bent on
destroying his own and enemy soldiers, and then acknowledges that the Bolsheviks
(“surprisingly”, p. 394) did not execute POWs but does not draw any conclusions from that; and
finally accuses both the Whites and bizarrely the Reds (twice) of having conducted
anti-Jewish pogroms.
Should
you read Ferguson’s “Pity of War”? Yes, I think it is definitely a very good book.
It is marred by author’s penchant for “originality” which implies revisionism, in
some cases, at any cost. This was probably also done in order to attract attention,
but in some cases, as in his discussion of the reasons underlying post-war
German economic policy, his “revisionism” is persuasive. The book is marred by the ideological blinkers
the author wears with delight. But it still provides a lot, perhaps more than
any other book on the First World War in the West, and is particularly
attractive to economists because it gives economic management center-stage and explains
German sudden collapse (a thing difficult to explain in any case) by economic
forces. Strangely, at the end, Ferguson goes back to the “unfashionable” (in
his own words, p. 140) domestic explanations for both the origin and the outcome
of the war, and thus—oh! horror---rejoins the reviled Marxists.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.