It has been long argued that American
income inequality was, in the past 40 years or so, exceptionally high compared
to other OECD countries. The latest results available by Luxembourg Income
Study that harmonizes income concepts across countries show inequality in
disposable (per capita) income in the US to be 41 Gini points, that is, higher
than in any other similarly rich country (Germany’s Gini is 32, British 35,
Italian 35, Dutch 28). So, this part is not controversial.
What is more controversial is technical
(as opposed to substantive) explanation for this “exceptionalism”. Some people have
argued that US market income inequality (that is, inequality before
government redistribution through social transfers and direct taxes) is not
much higher than elsewhere and that the entire explanation has to do with an insufficiently
redistributive state. In simple terms, the argument is that the market generates
same inequality in the US and Sweden, but Sweden redistributes much more through
pensions, unemployment benefits, social assistance etc., and also taxes the
rich more, so in the end disposable (after transfers and taxes) income inequality
in Sweden is less than in the United States.
Janet Gornick, Nathaniel Johnson and I
have recently looked at this more carefully. Without going through all explanations (which can be found in the paper here), we conclude that this is not entirely true:
US market income inequality is generally greater than in other rich countries and the American state redistributes less. So, we argue, both the underlying
(market) inequality is high and redistribution is relatively weak.
But one can go further than that, and
ask the following question: what part of redistribution is “weak”: is it that
US transfers are small and not sufficiently pro-poor, or is it that US direct
taxes are not sufficiently progressive?
Now, I look at that issue in the
following way. I define as “poor” the bottom 40% of individuals when people are
ranked by their market income inclusive of government-paid pensions (social security
in the US) which can be regarded as deferred wages. I then look at how the income share of these
very same people varies as we include other social transfers and finally as we
deduct direct taxes. (Note that this calculation can be done only if you have
access to micro data, as is the case with LIS data, because you need to “fix” these people and look at their
income and income share as they go through the process of redistribution.)
We expect that the share of
the “poor” increases as the state moves in to redistribute income. Indeed, in
2016 (the latest year for which we have US data), the “poor” received 11.7% of
overall market income, but their share went up to 13.4% of income when we include
all social transfers, and increased further to 15.8% when we include taxes too.
(Note again that these are the same people throughout). The gain for the “poor”
is thus 1.7 percentage points from social transfers (13.4-11.7) and an
additional 2.4 percentage points from taxes (15.8-13.4).
We can write it out:
In the US, the “poor” gain 1.7 points
thanks to social transfers and 2.4 points thanks to taxes.
So, the government really “works” in the
United States: it improves the position of the poorest people through
government transfers and direct taxes. But the question is, does it work well
enough?
One good comparator is Germany. We
control for different age distributions in the two countries and the fact that people retire earlier in Germany by
treating government pensions as deferred wages. But that still leaves (as mentioned
above) other social transfers like unemployment
benefits, family benefits (if any), welfare etc. So, in Germany in 2015, the “poor”
(defined the same way as in the US) earned 15.3% of all market income. Their share
went up to 18.3% when all social transfers are included, and further to 21.3% when
we include direct taxes as well. Thus the “poor” in Germany gained 3 percentage
points from social transfers (18.3-15.3) and 3 percentage points from taxes (21.3-18.3).
For Germany, we write:
The “poor” gain 3 points thanks to
transfers and then an additional 3 points thanks to taxes.
Thus, not only is the starting point
of the “poor” in Germany more favorable than in the United States (15.3% of market
income vs. only 11.7%) but they gain more from both social transfers and direct
taxes.
The results over time are shown in
two graphs below. The “poor” always gain from redistribution but US gains are
always smaller than German gains. What is noticeable is that the gains from
social transfers were about the same in the US and Germany until 1995, then
increased in both countries. In the US they were at their peak in 2010 when unemployment
benefits were extended by Obama and afterwards, since US welfare is very
modest, they rapidly went down.
Even more interesting is the
evolution of the gains from direct taxes. Here we see that the American “poor”
gain throughout less than the “poor” in Germany and that the level of gains does
not seem to change much in the US.
In conclusion, when we try to find the roots
of lower pro-poor redistribution in the US we can find them both in more modest
social transfers and in less progressive direct taxation. Combined with our
earlier finding of relatively high market income inequality in the US, this means
that American income inequality is “exceptional” because (a) underlying market
income inequality is high, (b) social transfers are modest, and (c) direct
taxes are not sufficiently progressive.
The policy implication is that
reduction in US income inequality is unlikely to be achieved through one of
these three channels alone but through a combination of “improvements” in each of them. For example,
through more accessible education and higher minimum wage to reduce the underlying
market income inequality; through introduction of family benefits or more
generous welfare; and finally through higher tax rates for the rich and higher
taxation of capital incomes. Although this might seem like an extremely ambitious
policy agenda, I think it is more reasonable to think that incremental changes
in all three channels are easier to pass legislatively than a much more substantial
change in any one of them alone. But it also means that if one wants to seriously
grapple with high inequality in the United States, only a combination of different
policies will do.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.